How “Accounting Mistakes” Cost California Taxpayers $32 Billion This Year

Spend more than 30 minutes watching TV in California and you will be bombarded by politicians proclaiming they single-handedly balanced the budget, brought prosperity back to the Silicon Valley alone, and turned water into wine. Yet, oddly, there is one thing none of them seem too quick to admit to. As CBS reports, the state office in charge of keeping track of California taxpayers’ money made tens of billions of accounting mistakes. CBS added it up and came up with a big number: $31.65 billion in errors. That’s more than the gross domestic product of Iceland and Jamaica combined.

 

 

As CBS reports,

Controller John Chiang’s office is the state’s financial watchdog, but an audit by the Bureau of State Audits claims the office’s accounting is off by billions of dollars.

 

The audit revealed:

  • $7.7 billion – Understated federal trust fund revenues and expenditures
  • $653 million – Overstated general fund assets and revenues
  • $8 billion – Overstated California State University’s bond debt
  • $9.1 billion – Reporting error that understated a public building construction fund
  • Also there was a deferred tax-revenue figure posted as $6.2 billion when it was actually $6.2 million.

All told, that’s more than $31 billion in mistakes.

 

Sacramento State accounting professor John Corless agrees with auditors saying those glaring mistakes should have been caught by somebody.

 

Someone’s not using their equipment right, and they’re not using their heads,” he said.
Republican consultant Mitch Zak is calling for an investigation.

 

“It’s offensive as a taxpayer,” he said. “There’s no consideration it appears if they misstate or mismanage my tax dollars that there’s any retribution.”

 

Chiang is running for state treasurer. His aides refused to go on camera for this story.

 

They said they concur with the assessment, and they blame high staff turnover and a lack of qualified staff, budget cuts, and late and incorrect data from numerous agencies.

Of course, we are sure that no one knows anything about it; no one is responsible for the errors; no one is accountable for the missing money; but a full-scale probe-y investigation will be launched… well played government. Doesn’t matter after all – it’s not their money.




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1oLv2tM Tyler Durden

Paul Volcker Proposes A New Breton Woods System To Prevent “Frequent, Destructive” Financial Crises

One of the conventional justifications by tenured economists for a fiat currency regime, especially as a replacement for a gold, or other hard currency, standard, is that the financial system has been far more stable under a non-gold standard regime.

While we have frequently shown that this assessment is flawed, the interpretation of the data is always a matter of opinion, and usually breaks down based on ideological conviction: be it Keynesian or Austrian. However, one person whose view carries significant weight among the Keynesian school of thought is none other than former Fed chairman Paul Volcker. Which is why we found it surprising that it was Volcker himself who, on May 21 at the annual meeting of the Bretton Woods Committee, said that “by now I think we can agree that the absence of an official, rules-based cooperatively managed, monetary system has not been a great success. In fact, international financial crises seem at least as frequent and more destructive in impeding economic stability and growth.” We can, indeed, agree.

However, we certainly disagree with Volcker’s proposal for a solution to this far more brittle monetary system: a new Bretton Woods.

Because if there is one place where our view radically diverges with that of the Chairman emeritus of the Group of 30 and not to mention former Fed chairman, it is in the arena of institutional oversight of finance and economics: whereas he and his ilk want more deference to an “official, rules-based managed monetary system”, we believe that this merely sows the seeds of yet another system’s own destruction as it hindres efficient markets, fair price discovery and by definition results in a manipulated market whose purpose is to serve a given policy objective du jour, and in doing so pushes it ever further from an equilibrium point and raises the likelihood of even greater, and more violent crashes.

However, since it is the fate of the current centrally-planned regime to become even more centralized following its next inevitable crash, we can only sit back and muse at Volcker’s tongue-in-cheek prediction of what will almost certainly come next.

His full speech is presented below:

REMARKS BY PAUL A. VOLCKER AT THE ANNUAL MEETING OF THE BRETTON WOODS COMMITTEE WASHINGTON, DC – MAY 21, 2014 (pdf)

A NEW BRETTON WOODS???

Weeks ago, Dick Debs overcame my reluctance to participate in still another public meeting. And once that commitment was made, the inevitable question followed: ”Paul, we need a title for your remarks”.

Well, what could I say that could be new or provocative amid all the conversations about the markets, financial reforms in all their variety, or even the Volcker Rule itself?

Well, given the sponsorship of this meeting, what popped out of my mouth was, “What About a New Bretton Woods???” – with three question marks.

The two words, “Bretton Woods”, still seem to invoke a certain nostalgia – memories of a more orderly, rule-based world of financial stability, and close cooperation among nations. Following the two disasters of the Great Depression and World War II that at least was the hope for the new International Monetary Fund, and the related World Bank, the GATT and the OECD.

No one here was actually present at Bretton Woods, but that was the world that I entered as a junior official in the U.S. Treasury more than 50 years ago. Intellectually and operationally, the Bretton Woods ideals absolutely dominated Treasury thinking and policies. The recovery of trade, the opening of financial markets, and the lifting of controls on current accounts led in the 1950’s and 60’s to sustained growth and stability.

Even then there were recurrent stresses and strains, but the sense of a strong commitment to the new system prevailed: the potential resources of the IMF were enlarged, a network of swap agreements was created, and there was even some Treasury borrowing in foreign currencies! Today’s “quantitative easing” had a smaller-scale precedent in the early 1960’s. “Operation Twist”, was designed to keep long-term interest rates low as short-term rates were raised, at least in part to protect the dollar. Even more striking was the introduction of a variety of controls by the United States on the export of capital.

With prices stable in the United States, which still had a sizable current account surplus, the use of the dollar convertible into gold at the center of the system was seldom questioned.

Those essential conditions had changed by the time I returned to the Treasury in 1969, right on the front line in the conduct of monetary affairs. The ill-conceived Vietnam conflict and its fiscal and political consequences shook the financial ground. An insidious intellectual shift was also becoming important. Robert Triffen had persuasively pointed out the ultimate dilemma in building a monetary system and the provision of international liquidity on the base of a single national currency. The invention of the Special Drawing Rights was a response to that critique, but the limited provision of SDR’s and sense of commitment was not enough to suppress the spreading concerns.

More broadly, the rationale of a regime of “fixed but adjustable” exchanges rates came into question. Later, those doubts were reinforced by a larger intellectual framework. The mantra of “efficient markets” and “rational expectations” seemed to suggest a stable and effective framework for a financial system, domestic or international, would not be dependent on – indeed should be independent of – official rules and structure.

Whatever the intellectual shift, by the early 1970’s it became increasingly apparent that there needed to be a realignment – to my mind a substantial realignment – of the exchange rate relationship between the U.S. dollar and other leading currencies, most importantly at that point the Japanese yen. The suspension of gold convertibility of the dollar as a transitional means of inducing the realignment, however controversial at the time, became inevitable.

Efforts to reconstruct the Bretton Woods system, either partially at the Smithsonian or more completely in the subsequent negotiations of the Committee of 20, ultimately failed. The practical consequence, and to many the ideological victory, was a regime of floating exchange rates. Somehow, the intellectual and convenient political argument went, differences among national financial and economic policies, shifts in competitiveness and in inflation rates, all could be and would be smoothly accommodated by orderly movements in exchange rates.

The need to subject national policies to external influence could be greatly reduced and national economic sovereignty maintained.

Any need for controls, for official intervention in currency markets, even for stockpiles of national reserves would be greatly reduced, and even eliminated. In fact, the “system” (or as many would label it “non-system”) could proceed effectively even without enforcing a common approach to floating. De facto, a hybrid system – a lot of floating, some fixing, some “do as you please” – developed with little role for the IMF itself in managing the “system”. In fact, the occasional efforts to achieve cooperation in managing exchange rates – strikingly in the well-publicized agreements at the Plaza and the Louvre in the 1980’s – were in response to national initiatives, with the IMF essentially a by-stander.

By now I think we can agree that the absence of an official, rules-based cooperatively managed, monetary system has not been a great success. In fact, international financial crises seem at least as frequent and more destructive in impeding economic stability and growth.

The United States, in particular, had in the 1970’s an unhappy decade of inflation ending in stagflation. The major Latin American debt crisis followed in the 1980’s. There was a serious banking crisis late in that decade, followed by a new Mexican crisis, and then the really big and damaging Asian crisis. Less than a decade later, it was capped by the financial crisis of the 2007-2009 period and the great Recession. Not a pretty picture. At the least, we have been reminded that while free and open capital markets may be needed to support vigorous growth, they are also prone to crisis. The more complex, interrelated and free from official restraints, the greater the collective risk.

For years, the benefits were reflected in the enormous growth and the reduction in poverty of emerging economies. The contrasting concerns are reflected in the slowing of growth and productivity in the industrialized world.

We can all recite a rather long list of culprits contributing to the financial crisis: excessive leverage, outlandish compensation, failures in regulatory oversight, simple greed, and on and on. What I want to raise is what seems to be a neglected question. Amid all the market and institutional excesses, all the regulatory omissions, most of all, the legitimate questions about the underlying failures of national economic policies, has the absence of a well-functioning international monetary system been an enabling (or instigating) condition? Specifically, did the absence of international oversight, of discipline in financing, of exchange rate management permit – even encourage – unsustainable imbalances in international payments and in domestic economies to persist too long?

Many have pointed, for instance, to the huge imbalances at the beginning of this century in international payments between the United States on one side and China and Japan on the other – the largest economies in the world. Those imbalances were easily financed. The result was that a high degree of liquidity at low interest rates could be maintained in the United States, despite the virtual disappearance of domestic savings. The sub-prime mortgage phenomenon was an outgrowth. At the same time, exceptionally high levels of savings and investment in China supported exports without working toward a more balanced economy, including the domestic consumption that would be necessary to sustain Chinese growth in the years ahead.

Where was an effective adjustment mechanism? Was the “exorbitant privilege” of the dollar as a reserve currency also a “dangerous temptation” to procrastinate – an impediment to timely policy adjustments, risking eventual breakdown?

The current travails of the Eurozone (the equivalent of an absolute fixed exchange rate regime) carry interesting lessons. A single currency with the free flows of funds among the member states simply could not substitute for the absence of a unified banking system and incentives for disciplined and complementary national economic policies.

That is all a long introduction to a plea – a plea for attention to the need for developing an international monetary and financial system worthy of our time.

Implicitly, bits and pieces of needed reform are being recognized by strong efforts to standardize commercial bank capital requirements and, for the first time, to introduce liquidity standards. The need for official oversight and surveillance beyond the commercial banking system is well recognized, even if much remains to be done to develop and standardize practices. There is effort underway to achieve a common approach toward the resolution of failing financial institutions of systemic importance; it is hard to perceive of any successful resolution process that proceeds only nationally.

In the midst of crisis, in 2008 and 2009, an intellectual consensus was reached within the G-20 about the need for forceful fiscal and monetary policies. More or less coordinated official intervention in markets took place on an enormous scale. Cooperation among central banks helped deal with pressures on exchange markets. The provision of ample liquidity by the key national central bankers is still taking place as we meet. But those measures don’t really count as structural reforms.

Now, new questions have been raised about the sensitivity of markets in small and emerging economies to even small policy adjustments by the Federal Reserve. While the concerns and complaints of some officials in those countries at the time may seem exaggerated, the volatility of short-term capital flows does raise important issues. And, there can be no doubt that major changes in circumstances and policies in industrialized countries do inevitably have world-wide repercussions.

Well, even if you agree with my concerns, you will reasonably ask where the analysis leads. What is the approach (or presumably combination of approaches) that can better reconcile reasonably free and open markets with independent national policies, maintaining in the process the stability in markets and economies that is in the common interest?

That is a question I cannot answer today with a sense of conviction and practicality. What I do know is that governments do not have before them the necessary analysis and well-conceived approaches that could command attention and support.

The creation of the G-20 at the exalted level of Presidents and Prime Ministers has been a political accomplishment. The agreed changes in IMF governing structure are important in achieving a sense of political legitimacy for its governing structure and decision-making. But that is not enough – it means little without substantive agreement on the need for monetary reform and practical approaches toward that end.

We are a long way from that. But what can be done now is to lay the intellectual ground work for approaches that can, for instance, identify and limit prolonged and ultimately unsustainable imbalances in national payments. We should be able, within a broad range, to manage exchange rates among major currencies in a manner that discourages the extreme changes that are inconsistent with orderly adjustment. We can and should consider ways and means of encouraging – even insisting upon – needed balance of payments equilibrium.

Nor would I reject some re-assessment of the use of a single national currency as the dominant international reserve and trading vehicle. For instance, do we want to encourage or discourage so important a development as regional trade and currency areas?

A new Bretton Woods conference? We are long ways from that. But surely events have raised, whether we want to admit it or not, some fundamental questions that have been ignored for decades.

We may have escaped a repeat of the Great Depression of the 1930’s. Happily, despite all the political turmoil in parts of the world, we have also escaped, narrowly escaped, a financial collapse destructive of major economies and needed cooperation. But obviously, that is not enough.

All that has happened reinforces what we typically affirm: a strong, innovative and stable financial system is fundamental to open trade and to the prosperity of all nations. Participation in such a beneficial system that has become truly international implies certain responsibilities.

Walter Bagehot long ago set out succinctly a lesson from experience: “Money will not manage itself”. He then spoke from the platform of the Economist to the Bank of England. Today it is our mutual interdependence that requires a degree of cooperation and coordination that too often has been lacking on an international scale.

Can we not, in approaching that challenge, restore something of the spirit and conviction that characterized the planning, the negotiation and the management of the Bretton Woods System that I once knew 50 years ago? Our host today, the Bretton Woods Committee lights the candle, but we have a long way to go.




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1rzWuwz Tyler Durden

Spitznagel & Taleb On Inequality, Free Markets, & Inevitable Crashes

Originally posted at The National Review,

Inequality, Free Markets, and Crashes
 

Nassim Taleb and Mark Spitznagel talk about how government intervention postpones the inevitable.

By Nassim Taleb & Mark Spitznagel

 




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1wPGuqm Tyler Durden

Whatever The ECB Does This Week, It Won’t “Deliver A Significant Impulse To The Real Economy”

Ahead of this Thursday’s ECB meeting, speculation is rife about what Mario Draghi will announce, and as the following Nomura chart highlights most pundits are convinced that the most likely announcement is a cut in the refi and deposit rate with a probability of around 90%, an LTRO in distant third at 34%, and a full blown QE dead last with 10%.

However, as SocGen predicts, which is rather aggressive in its assumptions expecting a negative deposit rate of -0.1%, a targeted LTRO to “boost lending to the private sector”, and a “signal” of €300 billion in asset purchases, the bulk of this new-found liquidity will almost exclusively go to boost capital markets, and the wealth effect. As for the broader economy? “We do not expect the 5 June measures to deliver a significant impulse to the real economy. Should euro area policy makers step back further from austerity, this would lift the economy in the short-term. Ultimately, however, the euro area needs deep structural reform. For all the energetic talk and many promises, actual progress on this front remains all too slow.”

Which, as is all too clear by now, is precisely what QE does: it stimulates risk assets, and does little if anything to promote actual economic growth: for that Keynesian doctrine demands a surge in loan and credit-money creation, something Europe, with its -2.0% annual contraction in lending to the private sector, will hardly experience.

More observations from SocGen on what Draghi may announce this week:

With just four days left to the 5 June ECB meeting, the excitement is palpable. When President Draghi announced the OMT back in the summer of 2012, the impact on financial markets was spectacular; spreads narrowed, equities rallied and the euro appreciated. Consensus growth estimates, however, tracked lower (!) as the forecast for 2013 dropped from 0.5% to -0.4%. Granted, the ECB must be given some credit for the 1.2% growth now forecast for 2014. Notably, in easing market pressure on governments, fiscal drift also provided part of the answer. Recovery in key export markets was an additional boon.

 

Should the ECB deliver a truckload of liquidity on 5 June, we have no doubt that financial markets will rally. Short of announcing monetary financing of fiscal stimulus, which is forbidden by the Treaty, we believe that the impact on the real economy is likely to be very modest. As Italy prepares to take over the European Presidency, the hope is that Prime Minister Renzi will be able to drive a new European agenda delivering growth and jobs. Our concern remains that this will prove all too slow to give the medium-term growth outlook, of around 1.5%, the boost it really needs.

 

5 June shopping list: Negative deposit rate, targeted LTRO, ….

 

With numerous possibilities on the table, most forecasts for the ECB resemble a shopping list, with lots of items but not all equally important. Our ECB preview offers all the details, but of the major items we expect (1) a negative deposit rate (-0.1%), (2) a targeted LTRO to boost lending to the private sector, and (3) a signal of asset purchases – we look for €300bn of purchases in 2H14, split between €100bn of ABS and €200bn of European issues (EFSF/ESM, EIB, etc.) and liquid, high-grade privates assets.

 

 

In this first round, we do not expect to see large scale sovereign asset purchases. To trigger large-scale sovereign asset purchases, we believe a more significant deterioration of the outlook is required. Even then, we remain concerned that the ECB would not be able to make such purchases on a pari-passu basis.

 

Easier monetary policy conditions will feed through to the real economy through the following main channels:

  • A weaker euro will deliver higher import prices … and may be slow to impact exports: as we discussed on these pages a few weeks ago, the lesson from both the recent experiences of the BoE and BoJ is that a weaker currency may not do much to boost exports in the short-term, but will erode household purchasing power via higher import prices. Rules of thumb suggest that a permanent 10% depreciation of the trade weighted euro would boost GDP by around 0.7% in the first year after the shock. Our concern is that this elasticity may at present be lower for two main reasons. First, a significantly weaker euro could come with a new widening of peripheral spreads. Second, slowing demand in emerging economies, and China in particular, is unlikely to be offset by any price effect.
  • A negative deposit rate comes with a cost: the main motivation for a negative deposit rate is to weaken the currency. To our minds, this has already been factored in by markets and we think it unlikely that this measure will deliver much further euro depreciation. The experience from Denmark, however, illustrated that negative deposit rates also carry a cost.
  • Portfolio reallocation effects may even boost the euro … but wealth effects are slow to trickle down: should markets deliver a thumbs-up to the ECB on 5 June, then flows in the hunt for yield could deliver a very significant boost to euro area assets … and may even lift the euro! Stronger asset prices are welcome, but experience shows that such effects are again slow to trickle down to the real economy, unless the boost is to real estate prices.
  • Credit conditions are already favourable in the core – easing financial fragmentation would be helpful: the hope is that a targeted LTRO program would trigger a wave of SME lending, resulting in job creation across the euro area. It is worth recalling that in the core, SME lending conditions are already quite favourable. In the periphery, red tape and bureaucracy, already high debt levels and a lack of domestic demand are other factors holding back SMEs. Easing financial conditions for SMEs in the periphery is helpful, deep rooted structural reform would be even better.

 

In sum, we do not expect the 5 June measures to deliver a significant impulse to the real economy. Should euro area policy makers step back further from austerity, this would lift the economy in the short-term. Ultimately, however, the euro area needs deep structural reform. For all the energetic talk and many promises, actual progress on this front remains all too slow.

Also considering that once again just Draghi’s jawboning has managed to push the EURUSD lower by a massive 400 pips in the past month, from 1.40 to 1.36, the central banker may opt to do nothing at all, as the core target of ECB intervention, a weaker currency, has already been achieved. It is unclear if the former Goldmanite would risk this: after all as Deutsche Bank said, zero action by the ECB this week would destroy what credibility it may have left.

Which means that once again, well over 5 years into this “recovery”, the one segment of the population to benefit from whatever the ECB will unveil will be those very rich few who will immediately benefit from the surge in risk assets. As for everyone else, keep up the hope.

The only remaining question is how much of the ECB intervention has already been priced into risk assets. Considering the relentelss surge in both global stocks and bonds, one would be tempted to say that this is shaping up to be more of a “sell the news” type of event…




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1nUVjDP Tyler Durden

How Inflation Helps Keep The Rich Up And The Poor Down

Submitted by Jorg Guido Hulsmann via the Ludwig von Mises Institute,

The production of money in a free society is a matter of free association. Everybody from the miners to the owners of the mines, to the minters, and up to the customers who buy the minted coins — all benefit from the production of money. None of them violates the property rights of anybody else, because everybody is free to enter the mining and minting business, and nobody is obliged to buy the product.

Things are completely different once we turn to money production in interventionist regimes, which have prevailed in the West for the better part of the past 150 years. Here we need to mention in particular two institutional forms of monetary interventionism: (fraudulent) fractional reserve banking and fiat money. The common characteristic of both these institutions is that they violate the principle of free association. They enable the producers of paper money and of money titles to expand their production through the violation of other people’s property rights.

Banking is fraudulent whenever bankers sell uncovered or only partially covered money substitutes that they present as fully covered titles for money. These bankers sell more money substitutes than they could have sold if they had taken care to keep a 100-percent reserve for each substitute they issued.

The producer of fiat money (in our days, typically, paper money) sells a product that cannot withstand the competition of free-market moneys such as gold and silver coins, and which the market participants only use because the use of all other moneys is severely restricted or even outlawed. The most eloquent illustration of this fact is that paper money in all countries has been protected through legal-tender laws. Paper money is inherently fiat money; it cannot thrive but when it is imposed by the state.

In both cases, the production of money is excessive because it is no longer constrained by the informed and voluntary association of the buying public. In a free market, paper money could not sustain the competition of the far superior metal moneys. The production of any quantity of paper money is therefore excessive by the standards of a free society. Similarly, fractional reserve banking produces excessive quantities of money substitutes, at any rate in those cases in which the customers are not informed that they are offered fractional-reserve bank deposits, rather than genuine money titles.

This excessive production of money and money titles is inflation by the Rothbardian definition, which we have adapted in the present study to the case of paper money. Inflation is an unjustifiable redistribution of income in favor of those who receive the new money and money titles first, and to the detriment of those who receive them last. In practice the redistribution always works out in favor of the fiat-money producers themselves (whom we misleadingly call central banks) and of their partners in the banking sector and at the stock exchange. And of course inflation works out to the advantage of governments and their closest allies in the business world. Inflation is the vehicle through which these individuals and groups enrich themselves, unjustifiably, at the expense of the citizenry at large. If there is any truth to the socialist caricature of capitalism — an economic system that exploits the poor to the benefit of the rich — then this caricature holds true for a capitalist system strangulated by inflation. The relentless influx of paper money makes the wealthy and powerful richer and more powerful than they would be if they depended exclusively on the voluntary support of their fellow citizens. And because it shields the political and economic establishment of the country from the competition emanating from the rest of society, inflation puts a brake on social mobility. The rich stay rich (longer) and the poor stay poor (longer) than they would in a free society.

The famous economist Josef Schumpeter once presented inflation as the harbinger of innovation. As he saw it, inflationary issues of banknotes would serve to finance upstart entrepreneurs who had great ideas but lacked capital. Now, even if we abstract from the questionable ethical character of this proposal, which boils down to subsidizing any self-appointed innovator at the involuntary expense of all other members of society, we must say that, in light of practical experience, Schumpeter’s scheme is wishful thinking. Credit expansion financed through printing money is in practice the very opposite of a way to combat the economic establishment. It is the preferred means of survival for an establishment that cannot, or can no longer, sustain the competition of its competitors.

It would not be uncharitable to characterize inflation as a large-scale rip-off, in favor of the politically well-connected few, and to the detriment of the politically destitute masses. It always goes in hand with the concentration of political power in the hands of those who are privileged to own a banking license and of those who control the production of the monopoly paper money. It promotes endless debts, puts society at the mercy of monetary authorities such as central banks, and to that extent entails moral corruption of society.




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1kZgsvy Tyler Durden

On Repeat: NSA Slow Jam

Edward Snowden is back in the news after his
exclusive

interview
with NBC’s Brian Williams on Wednesday
night. 

Reason TV’s Snowden-inspired music video was originally
released June 14, 2013.

Original lyrics below:

LYRICS

You see me rolling around in a black Mercedes
cruising around town and it’s packed with ladies
Gotta keep it going yeah I’m roaming the map
No I never stop until I find something to tap

Awww yeah…

[CHORUS]
Nokia, iPhone, Galaxy 3
Facebook and your search history
Gmail, voicemail, I’m gonna grab it
if it’s got an on/off switch, baby, I’ll tap it

I’m making a list, checking it twice
it doesn’t matter the message or even kind of device
Every pic your daughter sends? We’ve got it ingrained
Why do you think Anthony Weiner wants back in the game?

Surveilling reporters, don’t ever forget it
I got so many AP docs you’d think I’m getting college credit
Yeah we’re saving your searches, that’s just a reality
“Yes We Can” ain’t just a slogan it’s our view on legality

[CHORUS]

I’ll tell you this, sir, I greatly abhor
your violating the Constitution upon which you swore
and a full investigation is needed and more
You ever Google Justin Bieber pics? I yield back the floor…

Look, this is not a big deal? Why are you having a cow?
Look at all these innocent people we can focus on now?
Who cares about civil “rights?” I mean, do we all really need
em?
So you’ll oppose the individual mandate? Why do you hate
freedom?

Look, with front-facing cameras our intel has grown
Look at the video we’ve collected from this year alone
This is outrageous, we should be able to use the bathroom
freely!
Look just the other, wait, hello? Hi. How’d you get this number?
Really?

Nothing is private anyway, we’re posting on walls
So what’s the big deal if the government is saving your
calls?
We share our info with companies, this debate should be
chilled
Everybody come quick! A straw man has been killed!

So the next time you’re up late and you’re surfing your
phone
Let me reassure you, girl, that you’re not alone
But if you don’t think the surveillance state is really ideal
Text yourself about it, let us know how you feel.

 

from Hit & Run http://ift.tt/1wPanae
via IFTTT

19-Month-Old Toddler in Critical Condition After Cops Throw Flash Bang Grenade into Playpen

Screen Shot 2014-06-01 at 1.24.59 PMJust in case you aren’t already convinced that the “war on drugs” is the biggest waste of time, energy, and money imaginable, perhaps the following tragic tale will push you over the edge. This story touches on several very important themes that I highlight quite often on this site. Specifically, it demonstrates the dangers of the militarization of the U.S. police force, combined with the increased use of SWAT raids on homes of Americans who in many cases have committed non-violent offenses and victimless “crimes.”

One of the most shocking statistics I have come across in this regard is the fact that there are now 50,000 SWAT raids happening annually in America. Many of these are in response to minor “crimes,” if you can even call them that, and provide the police with the opportunity to play warrior cop. Earlier this year, I highlighted the disturbing video of a SWAT raid in Iowa, in which the cops were going after credit card fraud. Last year, I highlighted a SWAT raid against an organic farm in Texas. Is this Afghanistan, or a supposedly free country?

continue reading

from Liberty Blitzkrieg http://libertyblitzkrieg.com/2014/06/01/19-month-old-toddler-in-critical-condition-after-cops-throw-flash-bang-grenade-into-playpen/
via IFTTT

The Memorial Day Gold Massacre – When HFTs Forget The World’s On Vacation

As the rest of America began to relax last Monday with a patriotic beer in their hand and a never-forget-hotdog stuffed in their mouth, the machines that run the gold manipulation market appeared to forget that the world was on vacation. The WFT moment that we described here, appears – thanks to Nanex detailed analysis – to have been the actions of yet another rogue HFT algorithm roller-coastering through an after-hours order book in gold futures. Un-rigged?

Via Nanex,

HFT Roller Coaster Algo Runs in After Hours Gold

1. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures Top and Depth of Book. 
The cumulative size of orders in explodes from a normal 250 to over 2,500 contracts and most of this size is at the top of book (best bid/ask).



2. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures quote spread.
Note the wild price oscillation between $1275 and $1320.



3. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures trades.
Trading stops at 13:00



4. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures quote spread – Zoom 1 of Chart 2.



5. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures quote spread.  Zoom 2 of Chart 2.



6. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures Depth of Book.



7. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures Depth of Book.



8. June 2014 Gold (GC) Futures Depth of Book.



 

So while the world shrugged it off as yet another fat finger, it was real orders, not shitty data – from an HFT algo gone wild… welcome to the new unrigged markets…




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1kxQIlo Tyler Durden

New Massive Federal Database To Hold Financial Information of 100s Of Millions of Americans

Submitted by Mike Krieger of Liberty Blitzkrieg blog,

The war on privacy continues unabated, as the U.S. government continues to prove time and time again that it views the citizenry as a bunch of cattle to be branded, herded and dealt with at will. It doesn’t seem to bother anyone in the establishment that the public has lost all faith in institutions and so-called “authority” (a concept which I do not believe in to begin with). The evidence of a growing number of Orwellian databases being created has been available for quite some time. Most recently, I covered this topic in the following articles:

FBI Plans to Have 52 Million Photos in Facial Recognition Database by 2015

Guess What’s Hidden in the Immigration Bill? A National Biometric Database for Citizens

Moving along, the public faces another sinister and unacceptable invasion to our privacy. A national financial database is being planned, which would contain the most intimate details of our entire financial lives. It may apply to as many as 227 million Americans. We learn from the Washington Examiner that:

As many as 227 million Americans may be compelled to disclose intimate details of their families and financial lives — including their Social Security numbers — in a new national database being assembled by two federal agencies.

 

The Federal Housing Finance Agency and the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau posted an April 16 Federal Register notice of an expansion of their joint National Mortgage Database Program to include personally identifiable information that reveals actual users, a reversal of previously stated policy.

 

FHFA will manage the database and share it with CFPB. A CFPB internal planning document for 2013-17 describes the bureau as monitoring 95 percent of all mortgage transactions.

 

FHFA officials claim the database is essential to conducting a monthly mortgage survey required by the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008 and to help it prepare an annual report for Congress.

 

Critics, however, question the need for such a “vast database” for simple reporting purposes.

 

In a May 15 letter to FHFA Director Mel Watt and CFPB Director Richard Cordray, Rep. Jeb Hensarling, R-Texas, and Sen. Mike Crapo, R-Idaho, charged, “this expansion represents an unwarranted intrusion into the private lives of ordinary Americans.”

Mel Watt is one of the slimiest members of Congress, and that’s saying a lot.

Critics also warn the new database will be vulnerable to cyber attacks that could put private information about millions of consumers at risk. They also question the agency’s authority to collect such information.

Excellent. Once a cyber attack does compromise this idiotic database then we will be told we must give the NSA even more power to protect us from their own screwup. As usual.

The two agencies will also assemble “household demographic data,” including racial and ethnic data, gender, marital status, religion, education, employment history, military status, household composition, the number of wage earners and a family’s total wealth and assets.

 

The mortgage database is unprecedented and would collect personal mortgage information on every single-family residential first lien loan issued since 1998. Federal officials will continue updating the database into the indefinite future.

 

FHFA has two contracts with CoreLogic, which boasts that it has “access to industry’s largest most comprehensive active and historical mortgage databases of over 227 million loans.”

 

Cordray confirmed in his January testimony that CoreLogic had been retained for the national mortgage database.

 

“When you look at the kinds of data that are going to be collected on individuals, just about anything about you is going to be in this database,” he told the Examiner in an interview.

 

Meyster said she was unconvinced. “It seems they’re just adding information and they’re not really stating where it’s going or what it’s going to be used for. There’s no straightaway answer. They say they are trying to assemble as much information that they can.”

 

The Chamber of Commerce said that while Congress did ask for regular reports, it never granted FHFA the authority to create the National Mortgage Database.

 

“Congress did not explicitly require (or even explicitly authorize) the FHFA to build anything resembling the NMD,” the Chamber told Watt in its May 16 letter.

Oh so the agencies are just acting like tyrants without Congressional approval? Shocker.

A December report from the Government Accountability Office on breaches containing personally identifiable information from federal databases shows unlawful data breaches have doubled, from 15,140 reported incidents in 2009 to 22,156 in 2012.

Full article here.




via Zero Hedge http://ift.tt/1tzF2DZ Tyler Durden