2 Hospitalized After ‘White Powdery Substance’ Discovered At Ted Cruz Campaign Office

Less than an hour after CNN reported that two envelopes tainted with the deadly poison ricin had been intercepted at a Pentagon Mail Facility (the pieces of mail were addressed to Defense Secretary Jim Mattis and Navy Admiral John Richardson), the Weekly Standard reported that an envelope containing a “white powdery substance” was received by Ted Cruz’s Houston campaign headquarters.

Multiple fire trucks and at least one hazmat truck responded to the scene after the letter was opened by campaign staff, who promptly reported it to authorities.

According to WS, two people were hospitalized following exposure to the powder, though the Houston Fire Department later confirmed that the substance didn’t test positive for anything harmful.

Still, that both Cruz’s office and the Pentagon received these envelopes on the same day seems like a most unusual coincidence.

via RSS https://ift.tt/2P5lGJs Tyler Durden

The ACLU Sponsors an Ad Comparing Brett Kavanaugh to Bill Cosby and Harvey Weinstein

The American Civil Liberties Union is not merely opposing Brett Kavanaugh’s confirmation to the Supreme Court. The group has also spent a million dollars to run attack ads in several states comparing Kavanaugh to convicted sexual predator Bill Cosby.

“We’ve seen this before: denials from powerful men,” says the ad’s narrator. We then see images of #MeToo villains: former President Bill Clinton, former talk show hosts Matt Lauer and Charlie Rose, former studio executive, Harvey Weinstein, Cosby, and finally Kavanaugh. The implication is clear: Kavanaugh is just like them.

The ad is running in Nebraska, Colorado, West Virginia, and Alaska, and it is aimed at persuading fence-sitting senators to vote no on Kavanaugh.

The ACLU’s decision to formally oppose Kavanaugh was an unusual move for the organization, which almost never takes a position on judicial nominees. The decision to actively fight Kavanaugh by linking the uncorroborated allegations against him to the much more definitive, actually proven misbehavior committed by Cosby and others is something else: nakedly partisan.

It’s one thing to say that Kavanaugh is not the best choice for the Supreme Court. It’s quite another to prematurely lump him in with Clinton, Cosby, and Weinstein. I would have thought such tactics were beneath the ACLU. This is a shameful moment for a once-great organization.

from Hit & Run https://ift.tt/2NhwiTJ
via IFTTT

Kavanaugh Carnival Continues: Exposing Ford’s Paper On “Creating Artificial Memories”

Authored by Mike Shedlock via MishTalk,

The carnival continues with interesting twists such as Ford’s paper about using self-hypnosis to create memories

The Federalist reports Kavanaugh Accuser Co-Authored Study Citing Use of Hypnosis to Retrieve Memories.

Christine Blasey Ford, a California woman who has accused Supreme Court nominee Brett Kavanaugh of attempted rape in the 1980’s, co-authored an academic study that cited the use of hypnosis as a tool to retrieve memories in traumatized patients. The academic paper, entitled “Meditation With Yoga, Group Therapy With Hypnosis, and Psychoeducation for Long-Term Depressed Mood: A Randomized Pilot Trial,” described the results of a study the tested the efficacy of certain treatments on 46 depressed individuals. The study was published by the Journal of Clinical Psychology in May 2008.

While the paper by Ford and several other co-authors focused on whether various therapeutic techniques, including hypnosis, alleviate depression, it also discussed the therapeutic use of hypnosis to “assist in the retrieval of important memories” and to “create artificial situations” to assist in treatment.

Ford’s paper cited a controversial 1964 paper on the use of hypnosis to treat alcoholics and claimed that “hypnosis could be used to improve rapport in the therapeutic relationship, assist in the retrieval of important memories, and create artificial situations that would permit the client to express ego-dystonic emotions in a safe manner.” The study by Ford and her co-authors also used “self-hypnosis” to help treat their randomized sample of patients.

The 2004 text by Spiegel and Spiegel referenced by Ford and her fellow researchers discusses in detail the use of hypnotism, and even self-hypnotism, to recover memories from traumatic episodes.

“Remember that all hypnosis is really self-hypnosis,” the authors of the referenced 2004 text on hypnotism wrote. “[T]herefore, therapists are only tapping into their patients’ natural ability to enter trance state.”

The authors noted that hypnosis as a means of recovering traumatic memories could also lead to the “contamination” of those memories.

“Patients are highly suggestible and easily subject to memory contamination,” they noted.

Carnival Continues

With nearly everyone’s mind made up, despite the inconsistencies, the carnival will continue culminating in a final vote later this week or next.

This Week Says McConnell

Senate Majority Leader Mitch McConnell (R-Ky.) said the Senate will hold a Vote on Brett Kavanaugh’s Supreme Court Nomination This Week.

If the Vote Fails?

Why not start the process all over? With a new candidate?

Don’t be silly!

Lindsey Graham says If Kavanaugh Vote Fails, Trump Should Re-Nominate Him.

Demagoguery Zoo

Were Trump to renominate Kavanaugh, I believe that would constitute the ultimate political circus.

Strike that. This is neither a circus nor a carnival.

This is a purposeful media- and politically-sponsored demagoguery zoo with no cages and no zookeeper.

via RSS https://ift.tt/2zN9vMb Tyler Durden

State Department Demands Spouses of Gay Diplomats, U.N. Staff Get Legally Married to Visit—Even if They Can’t

Gay United Nations flagThe State Department has implemented a new policy requiring gay foreign diplomats and United Nations staffers to be legally married in order to get visas for their spouses. This is sparking a bit of anger, because some of them simply can’t do that.

After legal recognition of gay marriages became the law of the land, states, companies, and institutions began winding down programs providing benefits for the “domestic partnership” systems they had set up as an alternative. Gay couples would now need to tie the knot if they wanted to be treated the same as straight couples.

That is, on the surface, what appears to be happening with the State Department. In a letter sent in July, which attracted more widespread notice after former U.S. Ambassador to the U.N. Samantha Power tweeted about it last Friday, the State Department announced that it is ending a nine-year-old program allowing nonimmigrant travel visas for same-sex domestic partners to join their loved ones in the United States. Starting yesterday, if these partners want come to the U.S., they have to be legally married in order to qualify for the visas.

But gay marriage is still not legally recognized in most countries. Just 28 countries legally recognize gay marriages, either across the whole nation or in certain jurisdictions within them. And letter makes it clear that a marriage must be legally recognized in the couple’s home country to count. They can’t come to America, tie the knot here, and then get visas.

There is an exception, and it’s a bit strange. If a country doesn’t recognize gay marriages, but nevertheless treats same-sex couples from the United States the same as married heterosexual couples, the State Department will issue a visa:

As a matter of principle and reciprocity, in countries where same-sex marriage is not legally available and the sending State is unable to accept the accreditation of the same-sex spouses of members of the U.S. diplomatic and consular posts abroad, the same-sex domestic partner would not be eligible for the derivative A-1 or A-2 visa and will not be accepted for accreditation as a member of the family forming part of the household, eligible for the same privileges and immunities as a spouse while the principal serves in the United States.

Partners have until the end of the year to get married or go home.

When the Washington Blade (a gay publication in D.C.) took note of the letter in August, a State Department official told it that the change is about “promoting fairness.” The people affected don’t see it that way. Alfonso Nam—the president of UN-GLOBE, an advocacy group for gay and transgender U.N. employees—told the Blade this policy of “fairness” will make it very difficult, if not impossible, for the partners of some gay diplomats and U.N. staffers to remain in the United States.

“With this decision, the U.S. State Department is imposing the standard of marriage over all other forms of legal unions,” Nam told the Blade. “This will have a negative impact on same-sex couples working for the U.N. who already face limited choices when it comes to being able to get married.”

Foreign Policy reports that the change will affect at least 10 United Nations employees. Such a small number highlights how weirdly cruel and unnecessary the policy change is. There is not some big flood of foreigners in fake gay relationships using their jobs with the United Nations to sneak their way into the country. And if the intent is to try to encourage other countries to recognize marriage too, there certainly aren’t enough people being affected to be influential in any way.

Instead it comes off as a pointless, petty change designed to hurt a handful of gay families from other countries. It’s another piece of evidence that President Donald Trump’s administration isn’t just waging some war on illegal immigration; it is hostile even to legal immigration—and even, in this case, to long-term foreign visitors.

from Hit & Run https://ift.tt/2xS9IMQ
via IFTTT

US Threatens To Destroy Russian Nuclear-Capable Missile System If Necessary

U.S. Ambassador to NATO Kay Bailey Hutchison on Tuesday warned that the U.S. could be forced to “take out” missiles Russia is developing that violate a Cold War-era treaty. If completed, the 9M729 Russian missile system could give it the capability to launch a missile strike on Europe with little or no notice, the Associated Press reported.

“It is time now for Russia to come to the table and stop the violations,” Hutchison told reporters in Brussels, where US Defense Secretary Jim Mattis would later meet his NATO counterparts. She added that if the system became operational, the U.S. “would then be looking at the capability to take out a missile that could hit any of our countries in Europe and hit America.”

The Novator 9M729 missile system

Hutchison also urged Russia to cease development of the missile system, which fits into a class of banned weapons under the 1987 Intermediate-range Nuclear Forces Treaty. 

“There will come a point in the future in which America will determine that it has to move forward with a development phase that is not allowed by the treaty right now,” Hutchison said.

Earlier in the day, NATO Secretary General Jens Stoltenberg urged Russia to be more transparent, and explain its alleged breaches of the INF Treaty.

She also noted that the US had no intentions of violating the 1987 Intermediate-Range Nuclear Forces Treaty (INF), adding, however, that it might occur because of Russia. The pact bans countries from developing land-based cruise missiles with a range of between 310 and 3,410 miles. NATO officials have said the nascent Russian system fits into that category, the AP reported.

According to the US, the new Russian 9M729 missile systems violate the conditions of the pact, as they give Russia the possibility of launching a nuclear strike in Europe with little or no notice.

Meanwhile, Russia’s Foreign Ministry has said that the 9M729 missiles correspond to Russia’s obligations under the INF Treaty and have not been upgraded and tested for the prohibited ranges. Moscow also noted that Washington had never provided any evidence that Russia had violated the agreement because such proof does not exist. Earlier in July, Russian Defense Minister Sergei Shoigu claimed that the United States is violating the treaty by deploying in Europe missile defense systems with launchers, which might be used for firing Tomahawk cruise missiles.

Hutchison’s comments come a day before Defense Secretary James Mattis was scheduled to meet with other NATO officials. Mattis said he intends to bring up the missile issue during the meeting according to the AP.

Concerns over the missile system mark the latest sign of tensions between Russia and the rest of the world. Most recently, the U.S. imposed sanctions on Russia after the intelligence community determined that Russia interfered in the 2016 election. Multiple Russians have since been charged in special counsel Robert Mueller’s investigation into election meddling.

 

via RSS https://ift.tt/2O0J7Ha Tyler Durden

Junk Bond Spreads Just Dropped To The Lowest Since 2007

The incredibly shrinking junk bond spread just passed a historic landmark when the Bloomberg Barclays U.S. Corporate High Yield index broke below the lowest spread since before the financial crisis this morning, dipping to 309bps, the tightest level since late 2007. This means that the extra yield over U.S. Treasuries that investors demand to own USD-denominated junk debt collapsed to the least in more than a decade.

The key reason cited by analysts has been the accelerating shrinkage in high-yield supply, as last month was the slowest September for junk bond issuance since 2011, while the high yield market as a whole has been contracting as investors have shifted their focus to leverage loans where demand, as discussed recently, has been unprecedented.

Meanwhile, fed hikes have been rising all boats, pushing debt yields across the fixed income space higher, however unlike investment grade bonds, they have a more nuanced impact on junk which is another reason why the spread has been contracting. That said, once the time comes to refinance, these issuers may feel pain as they find themselves rolling debt into notably higher interest rates. Meanwhile, thanks to the strong economy, earnings even for the distressed sector have been solid with no unexpected blow ups (think the energy sector in the aftermath of the oil recession in late 2015/early2016).

The biggest winners in the half were pharmaceutical names, but virtually every other industry group has outperformed with the obvious exception of department stores. The picture for automakers has been mixed too, although here the catalyst has been rising costs due to tariffs and confusion over Brexit: Jaguar Land Rover bonds have done worse than Tesla’s, while Fiat Chrysler’s have outperformed the broader index, according to Bloomberg.

The collapse in spreads has been a boon to hedge funds, with distressed debt investors generating a 6.6% return through August, outperforming the overall 0.3% gain for the broader industry and the negative total return for Investment Grade bonds.

For some of them, today’s event is a sell signal: “It’s a good time to monetize,” said Victor Khosla, founder of the $8.5 billion U.S. fund Strategic Value Partners LLC, which invests in distressed debt. “When high-yield spreads get to be this tight, when markets are this strong, you’re not buying as much as you’re selling.”

To be sure, the collapse in spread has taken place even as overall junk bond leverage has risen to all time highs.

Others have noted that the last time spreads were this tight, the recession was about to start.

Meanwhile, for those willing to call it a day on US junk, the next big opportunities may be cropping up in emerging markets. Argentina and Brazil are among potentially promising markets as a mix of rising interest rates, currency devaluations and exiting foreign capital puts companies under pressure, according to David Tawil, co-founder and president of Maglan Capital.

Others looking for distressed opportunities will look to Asia, where widening spreads on Indonesian junk dollar bonds, accelerating defaults on Chinese corporate bonds and nonperforming loans in India suggest that there will be plenty of choices to pick from.

Not everyone is convinced that the party in US junk is over: some have said that energy names, a key component of the High Yield index, are benefiting from oil prices at 4 year highs. Others, such as Bloomberg’s Sebastian Boyd, observe that there is a seasonal pattern of outperformance in the month after quarter-end leading up to results season: “If it holds, we could keep grinding tighter for another couple of weeks.”

The question is just how much tighter can spreads collapse as soon return on simple cash will provide a higher return than risking capital on stressed companies that have never been more leveraged.

via RSS https://ift.tt/2ybyiaS Tyler Durden

Go Ahead and Ignore Those #BreakUpWithBacon Ads

The activist group Physicians Committee for Responsible Medicine is running an anti-bacon campaign in the District of Columbia. The campaign includes advertisements on TV and at bus stops throughout the city under the slogan #BreakUpWithBacon.

Neal Barnard, founder of the Physicians Committee group, said the leading cause of cancer deaths for men and women in the United States is lung cancer, largely attributable to tobacco, and the second leading cause is colorectal cancer, reports The Washington Post. “The message is, ‘Bacon is the new tobacco,'” Barnard said. In support of this assertion, Barnard cites data from the International Agency for Research on Cancer that finds that eating 50 grams of processed meat daily, equivalent to about 4 strips of bacon, correlates with an 18 pecent increase in the risk of getting colorectal cancer.

Should you quit bacon? First, eating 50 grams daily amounts to a bit over 40 pounds of bacon annually. Keep in mind that only about 18 million Americans consumed more than 5 pounds of bacon annually in 2018.

Second, the lifetime risk of developing colorectal cancer in the U.S. is about 4.49 percent for men and 4.15 percent for women. Roughly calculated, an 18 percent increase means that the risk would rise to 5.3 percent for men and to 4.9 percent for women. In contrast, the lifetime risk of lung cancer among current male and female smokers is 17.2 and 11.6 percent, respectively, compared to the corresponding risks of male and female non-smokers at 1.3 and 1.4 percent. In other words, smoking boosts lung cancer risk by more than 1,000 percent compared to eating bacon, which increases the risk by 18 percent.

The far more effective way for a person to reduce the risk of getting and dying from colon cancer is to receive regular colonoscopies. For example, a recent study reports that colonoscopies help reduce the incidence of colorectal cancer by 89 percent.

I don’t doubt the sincerity of the folks associated with the Physicians Committee for Responsible Medicine, but comparing the cancer risks of bacon consumption to those of smoking basically amounts to scaremongering.

Disclosure: A precancerous polyp was removed during my first colonoscopy in my early 50s. Two subsequent colonoscopies have found no additional polyps. I intend to continue eating the occasional strip of bacon and to submitting to colonoscopies every five years or so.

from Hit & Run https://ift.tt/2OA0f6s
via IFTTT

Ethnic Nationalists Won the Quebec Election. What Fueled Their Rise?

To the surpise and chagrin of multicultural Canada, it turns out that Quebec separatism, long thought a dead movement, was actually in hibernation. The Coalition Avenir Quebec (CAQ) won a majority government, trouncing the establishment separatist party. The victory marks the first time since 1966 that the province won’t be governed by either the left-leaning Liberals or the social democratic separatist Parti Québécois.

The CAQ is only seven years old but its agenda should have a familiar ring to Americans. The party combines populism and center-right economic policy prescriptions with a brand of hardline ethnic nationalism that would make Stephen Miller blush. Premiere-designate Francois Legault aims to cut immigration by 20 percent, strengthen the province’s existing ban on face covering, and expel newcomers who fail a test of French literacy and Quebecois values.

Why is this happening in Canada? Wasn’t Canada supposed to be a gentle haven of multiculturalism with a bilingual, bhangra-dancing prime minister, that opened its borders to 55,000 Syrian war refugees and American exiles self-deporting from Trump’s America?

The temptation to see Trump as a bellwether for La belle province should be resisted. Nor can we blame Canada for Quebec’s nationalistic turn. Though it’s known as the Great White North, Canadians overall have maintained positive attitudes towards immigrants of every hue and shade for the last 20 years, even as the numbers of foreign born have swelled to over 20 percent of the population.

No, the forces bringing the caquistes to power in Quebec City are home grown and they’ve been a long time in the making. Hostility toward immigrants is deeply embedded in Quebec’s separatist political culture, predating Trump’s candidacy by decades, traceable to the failed 1995 referendum on Quebec independence.

The separatists lost that contest, which would’ve redrawn the map of North America, by the agonizingly close vote of 50.58 percent to 49.42 percent. When the final results were tallied, and it became clear to all that Canada would not break apart, Quebec’s separatist Premier (and Captain Kangaroo lookalike) Jacques Parizeau infamously pointed the finger at immigrants for shattering the dream of an independent, French-speaking nation.

“It’s true, it’s true we were beaten, basically, by what? By money and ethnic votes, essentially,” (“C‘est vrai qu’on a été battus, au fond, par quoi? Par l’argent puis des votes ethniques, essentiellement”) said a belligerent Parizeau, going off script, to an audience of his howling supporters at the Palais des Congress in Montreal.

Many understood “money” as a rhetorical jab at Montreal’s Jewish community. As a culturally distinct minority of English-speaking Canadians, Jewish Quebeckers overwhelmingly opposed nationhood. The premiere’s raw remark so succinctly summed up the post-referendum resentment that it’s still periodically revived, 23 years later, whenever Canadian pundits wish to remind readers how ugly nationalist politics can be.

But Monsieur Parizeau had a point. Immigrants who’ve chosen Canada as their home have never been persuaded to abandon it. And while most of Quebec’s immigrants are native French speakers, few take interest in the acrimonious language wars that animate the separatist cause. With the 1995 referendum decided by a single percentage point, immigrants are arguably the reason why Quebec remains a Canadian province today.

Separatists didn’t always see immigrants as an obstacle to nationhood. Gérard Godin, a poet-politician, and the first immigration minister of the Parti Québécois, argued in the early 1980s that foreign-born citizens were essential to the separatist project. Immigrants, he hoped, would be welcomed by the province; they would identify as Québécois and then they would vote for independence.

Godin’s 1983 ode to immigrants, “Tango de Montréal,” is written in brick at the Mont Royal metro station.

Seven thirty in the morning in the Montreal metro
it’s full of immigrants
they get up early
in that world

so if the old heart of the city
is still beating
it’s thanks to them.

|||Mont Royal metro station. Photo by savard.photo on flickr.

from Hit & Run https://ift.tt/2xSz5y0
via IFTTT

Flake May Vote “No” On Kavanaugh Regardless Of FBI Findings

GOP Senator Jeff Flake of Arizona may not vote to confirm Supreme Court nominee Brett Kavanaugh regardless of the outcome of an FBI investigation he demanded last week, according to The Atlantic

Speaking with Jeffrey Rosen, the president of the Constitution Center, and Democratic Senator Chris Coons at The Atlantic Festival on Tuesday morning, Flake called the judge’s interactions with lawmakers “sharp and partisan.”

We can’t have that on the Court,” said the Arizona senator, who didn’t elaborate on which interactions he was referring to.

Flake’s “gentleman’s agreement” with Coons, from Delaware, led to the FBI reopening its investigation into Kavanaugh late last week. The bureau is examining the sexual-assault allegations of Christine Blasey Ford, who also testified on Thursday. –The Atlantic

Elaina Plott of The Atlantic caught up with Flake as he left the event and asked him if his comments meant that he would not vote for Kavanaugh, “even if the FBI cleared him by week’s end.” 

Flake “appeared rattled, and his handlers rushed him into the stairwell” reports Plott. 

“I didn’t say that …” he stammered. “I wasn’t referring to him.” 

Meanwhile, Flake has appeared to waffle in recent days over whether or not he will vote to confirm Kavinaugh. In a late Friday night interview with McCay Coppins of The Atlantic, Flake said he remained “unsettled” by the lack of clarity contained within the allegations – and instead pivoted to Democrat Chris Coons’s idea for the FBI investigation. 

“If it was anybody else, I wouldn’t have taken it as seriously. But I know Chris. … We trust each other,” said Flake. “And I thought, if we could actually get something like what he was asking for—an investigation limited in time, limited in scope—we could maybe bring a little unity.”

On stage Tuesday morning, Coons and Flake both expressed dismay about the partisan brawling over Supreme Court nominees. Coons called for “reduc[ing] the frequency with which we describe judges as wearing red or blue jerseys.” He argued that senators need to commit to reviving the practice of confirming nominees based on their qualifications, not ideology.

Speaking about politics more broadly, Flake echoed that sentiment: “We’ve got to come to a point again where failure to compromise … is punished at the ballot box, rather than rewarded.”

Is flake the most powerful lame duck politician in Washington right now? On Sunday, he admitted to 60 Minutes that he wouldn’t have thrown the Kavanaugh confirmation into disarray if he was running for office again. 

In other words, Flake knows his actions don’t reflect what his Republican constituency would prefer, and he doesn’t care. 

via RSS https://ift.tt/2P1HxBC Tyler Durden

Stocks Dip After Hawkish Powell Comments

Nothing’s gonna stop me now… appears to be the message from Fed Chair Jay Powell in his first post-rate-hike speech as he reassured the market that inflation is not a worry and The Fed will keep hiking rates into “extraordinary times.”….

Key takeaways from Powell’s remarks (via Bloomberg):

  • Powell expresses confidence that low unemployment won’t spur a takeoff in prices that would force the Fed to hike interest rates aggressively

  • One key quote: “The rise in wages is broadly consistent with observed rates of price inflation and labor productivity growth and therefore does not point to an overheating labor market”

  • Another: “Our course is clear: Resolutely conduct policy consistent with the FOMC’s symmetric 2 percent inflation objective, and stand ready to act with authority if expectations drift materially up or down”

  • And finally: “So long as inflation expectations remain anchored, a modest steepening of the Phillips curve would be unlikely to cause a significant rise in inflation or demand a disruptive policy tightening”

  • Powell doesn’t offer any hints at how high rates might go this cycle

Wage growth alone need not be inflationary, meanwhile the US is in extraordinary times where inflation is low as is unemployment.

“Our best estimates, however, suggest that so long as inflation expectations remain anchored, a modest steepening of the Phillips curve would be unlikely to cause a significant rise in inflation or demand a disruptive policy tightening. Once again, the key is the anchored expectations.”

This historically rare pairing of steady, low inflation and very low unemployment is testament to the fact that we remain in extraordinary times. Our ongoing policy of gradual interest rate normalization reflects our efforts to balance the inevitable risks that come with extraordinary times, so as to extend the current expansion, while maintaining maximum employment and low and stable inflation.”

The Bottom line? He’s saying the Fed is on track to stick with the program..

And stocks are modestly lower on that

Powell’s Full Prepared Remarks:

It is a pleasure and an honor to speak here today at the 60th Annual Meeting of the National Association for Business Economics (NABE). Since 1959, NABE has promoted the use of economics in the workplace and advanced the worthy purpose of ensuring that leading American businesses benefit from the insights of economists.

Today I will focus on the Federal Reserve’s ongoing efforts to promote maximum employment and stable prices. I am pleased to say that, by these measures, the economy looks very good. The unemployment rate stands at 3.9 percent, near a 20-year low. Inflation is currently running near the Federal Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) objective of 2 percent. While these two top-line statistics do not always present an accurate picture of overall economic conditions, a wide range of data on jobs and prices supports a positive view. In addition, many forecasters are predicting that these favorable conditions are likely to continue. For example, the medians of the most recent projections from FOMC participants and the Survey of Professional Forecasters, as well as the most recent Congressional Budget Office (CBO) forecast, all have the unemployment rate remaining below 4 percent through the end of 2020, with inflation staying very near 2 percent over the same period.

From the standpoint of our dual mandate, this is a remarkably positive outlook. Indeed, I was asked at last week’s press conference whether these forecasts are too good to be true–a reasonable question! Since 1950, the U.S. economy has experienced periods of low, stable inflation and periods of very low unemployment, but never both for such an extended time as is seen in these forecasts. Standard economic thinking has long offered an explanation for this: If unemployment were to remain this low for this long, employers would be pushing up wages as they compete for scarce workers, and rising labor costs would feed into more‑rapid price inflation faced by consumers.

This dynamic between unemployment and inflation is known as a Phillips curve relationship, and at times it can pose a fundamental tension between the two sides of the Fed’s mandate to promote maximum employment and price stability. Recent low inflation and unemployment have some analysts asking, “Is the Phillips curve dead?” Others argue that the Phillips curve still lurks in the background and could reemerge at any time to exact revenge for low unemployment in the form of high inflation.

My comments today have two main objectives. The first is to explain how changes in the Phillips curve help account for the somewhat surprising but broadly shared current forecasts of continued very low unemployment with inflation near 2 percent. At the risk of spoiling the surprise, I do not see it as likely that the Phillips curve is dead, or that it will soon exact revenge. What is more likely, in my view, is that many factors, including better conduct of monetary policy over the past few decades, have greatly reduced, but not eliminated, the effects that tight labor markets have on inflation. However, no one fully understands the nature of these changes or the role they play in the current context. Common sense suggests we should beware when forecasts predict events seldom before observed in the economy.

Thus, my second objective today is to explain, given this uncertainty about the unemployment-inflation relationship, the important role that risk management plays in setting monetary policy. I will explore the FOMC’s monitoring and balancing of risks as well as our contingency planning for cases when risk becomes reality.

Historical Perspective on Jobs and Inflation
Let us start with a look at the modern history of jobs and inflation in the United States. Figure 1 shows headline inflation and unemployment from 1960 to today and extended through 2020 using the average of median projections from both FOMC participants and the Survey of Professional Forecasters, and the CBO projections. As the figure makes clear, a multiyear period with unemployment below 4 percent and stable inflation would, if realized, be unique in modern U.S. data.

To understand the basis for these forecasts, it is useful to contrast two very different periods included in figure 1: From 1960 to 1985, and the period from 1995 to today. The first period includes the Great Inflation, and the latter includes both the Great Moderation and the distinctly immoderate period of the Global Financial Crisis and its aftermath.

Figure 2 shows unemployment and core, rather than headline, inflation in these two periods. While our inflation objective concerns headline inflation, switching to core inflation makes some relationships clearer by removing a good deal of variability due to food and energy prices, variability that is not primarily driven by labor market conditions or monetary policy.

There is a dramatic difference in the unemployment-inflation relationship across these two periods. During the Great Inflation, unemployment fluctuated between roughly 4 percent and 10 percent, and inflation moved over a similar range. In the recent period, the unemployment rate also fluctuated between roughly 4 percent and 10 percent, but inflation has been relatively tame, averaging 1.7 percent and never declining below 1 percent or rising to 2.5 percent. Even during the financial crisis, core inflation barely budged. As a thought experiment, look at the right panel and imagine that you could see only the red line (inflation), and not the blue line (unemployment). Nothing in the red line hints at a major economic event, let alone the immense upheaval around the time of the global financial crisis.

Notice that, in each period, there is only one episode in which unemployment drops below 4 percent. In the late 1960s, unemployment remained at or below 4 percent for four years, and during that time inflation rose steadily from under 2 percent to almost 5 percent. By contrast, the late 1990s episode of below-4-percent unemployment was quite brief, and during the episode and surrounding quarters inflation was reasonably stable and remained below 2 percent.

To explore the Phillips curve relationship in these two periods more closely, we need to bring in the concept of the natural rate of unemployment. In standard economic thinking, an unemployment rate above the natural rate indicates slack in the labor market and tends to be associated with downward pressure on inflation; unemployment below the natural rate represents a tight labor market and is associated with upward inflation pressure.

Figure 3 repeats figure 2 but replaces unemployment with labor market slack as measured by unemployment minus the CBO’s current estimate of the natural rate of unemployment at each point in time. Periods of tight labor markets are shaded. During the Great Inflation, inflation generally rose in the tight, shaded periods and fell in the unshaded ones, just as conventional Phillips curve reasoning predicts.

From 1995 to today, the large and persistent swings in the gap between unemployment and the natural rate were associated with, at most, a move of a few tenths in the inflation rate. Comparing the shaded and unshaded regions, you might see some association between slack and the minor ups and downs in inflation, but the pattern is not at all consistent. It is evidence like this that fuels speculation about the Phillips curve’s demise.

Whether dead, sick, or merely resting, many of the questions about the Phillips curve come down to figuring out what changed between these two periods, and why. Let us turn to a conceptual framework for examining these questions more systematically.

A Simple Framework for Understanding Changes in the Jobs-Inflation Relationship
A natural starting point is the simplest form of a Phillips curve equation, which posits that inflation this year is determined by some combination of current labor market slack, inflation last year, and some other factors that I will leave aside for this discussion (figure 4):

Inflation(t)=−BSlack(t)+CInflation(t−1)+Other(t)Inflation(t)=−BSlack(t)+CInflation(t−1)+Other(t)

The value of B is often referred to as the slope of the Phillips curve. With a larger value of B, any change in labor market slack translates into a bigger change in inflation. As we say, as B increases, the Phillips curve steepens. The value of C determines inflation’s persistence–that is, how long any given change in inflation tends to linger. As the value of C increases, higher inflation this year translates more into higher inflation next year. A particularly nasty case arises when B and C are both large. In this case, slack has a large effect on inflation, and that effect tends to be very persistent. One implication of a large C is that, if a boom drives inflation up, it will tend to stay up unless offset by a subsequent bust.

Figure 5 shows regression estimates of B and C, computed over 20-year samples starting with the sample from 1965 to 1984 and including each 20-year sample through 2017. During the Great Inflation samples, the value of C is near 1, meaning that higher inflation one year tended to translate almost one-for-one into higher inflation the next. The Phillips curve is also relatively steep in the Great Inflation samples, with 1 extra percentage point of lower unemployment converting into roughly 1/2 percentage point of higher inflation. Thus, the Great Inflation presented that nasty case just described.

Fortunately, things changed. The estimates of both B and C fall in value as the estimation sample shifts forward in time. In the most recent samples, the Phillips curve is nearly flat, with B very near zero, and C is about 0.25, meaning that roughly one fourth of any rise or fall in inflation carries forward. These results give numerical form to what we see in the right-hand panel of figure 3, covering the recent period: Large and persistent moves in the unemployment gap were associated with, at most, modest transitory moves in inflation.

What Led to the Changes in the Phillips curve?
These developments amount to a better world for households and businesses, which no longer experience or even fear the scourge of high and volatile inflation. To provide a sound basis for monetary policy, it is important to understand what happened and why, so we can avoid a return to the bad old days of the 1970s. Like many, I believe better monetary policy has played a central role.9

To understand the mechanism, let us ask how central banks could, presumably inadvertently, amplify and extend the duration of inflation’s response to labor market tightness. To do so, the central bank could persistently ease the stance of monetary policy in response to an uptick in inflation. No responsible central banker today would intentionally do this, but much research suggests that during the Great Inflation, misunderstandings about how the economy worked led the Fed effectively to behave in this manner. Some policymakers may have believed the misguided notion that accommodating permanently higher inflation could purchase permanently higher employment. Other policymakers misperceived the level of the natural rate of unemployment, which we now believe had shifted up markedly in the 1960s. With the higher natural rate, the labor market was much tighter and provided much greater upward pressure on inflation than policymakers realized in real time. As a result, they were continually “behind the curve.”

The channel through which monetary policy can amplify and extend inflation’s response to shocks becomes even stronger when we take account of expectations. If people come to expect that upward blips in inflation will result in ongoing higher inflation, they will build that view into wage and price decisions. In this case, people’s expectations become a force adding momentum to inflation, and breaking inflation’s momentum can require convincing people to change their minds and behavior–never an easy task. Arguably, this is why a federal funds rate near 20 percent–roughly 10 percent in real terms‑‑was required in the early 1980s to turn the tide on high inflation. The cost, in the form of very high unemployment, is clear in the Great Inflation figures. The Great Inflation taught us that a main task of monetary policy is to keep inflation expectations anchored at some low level.

This idea is behind the adoption in recent decades of inflation targets, such as the Fed’s 2 percent objective, by central banks around the world. When monetary policy tends to offset shocks to inflation, rather than amplifying and extending them, and when people come to expect this policy response, a surprise rise or fall in labor market tightness will naturally have smaller and less persistent effects on inflation. Research suggests that this reasoning can account for a good deal of the change in the Phillips curve relationship. It is also likely that many other factors have contributed to changes in inflation dynamics over recent decades. We do not fully understand the causes and implications of these changes, which raises risk management issues that I will take up now.

A Favorable Outlook, but What Could Go Wrong?
To set the stage, let us return to the situation facing the FOMC. The baseline forecasts of most FOMC participants and a broad range of others show unemployment remaining below 4 percent for an extended period, with inflation steady near 2 percent. I have made the case that this forecast is not too good to be true and does not signal the death of the Phillips curve. Instead, the outlook is consistent with evidence of a very flat Phillips curve and inflation expectations anchored near 2 percent.

But we still must face the cautionary advice to beware when forecasts point to rarely seen outcomes. As a way of heeding this advice, the Committee takes a risk management approach, which has three important parts: monitoring risks; balancing risks, both upside and downside; and contingency planning for surprises. Let me describe a few of the risks and how we are thinking about them.

Could Inflation Expectations Become Unanchored?
First is the risk that inflation expectations might lose their anchor. We attribute a great deal of the stability of inflation in recent years to the anchoring of longer-term inflation expectations. And we are aware that it could be very costly if those expectations were to drift materially. As you probably know from our public communications, we carefully monitor survey- and market-based proxies for expectations, and we do not see evidence of a material shift in longer-term expectations (figure 6). The survey measures have been particularly steady for some time. The financial market-based measures include both an expectations component and a volatile inflation premium component, so they tend to move around much more than the surveys, but we see no evidence of a material change in these measures, either.

The risks to inflation expectations are, of course, two sided. Until this summer, inflation had remained stubbornly below 2 percent for several years. And major economies in much of the world have been struggling mainly with disinflationary forces. Thus, we have been and will remain alert for possible downward drift in expectations. Some argue the contrary case–that by only gradually removing accommodation as the unemployment rate has fallen, the FOMC may have fallen behind the curve, thereby risking an upward drift in expectations. From the standpoint of contingency planning, our course is clear: Resolutely conduct policy consistent with the FOMC’s symmetric 2 percent inflation objective, and stand ready to act with authority if expectations drift materially up or down.

Could Inflation Pressures Move up More than Expected in a Hot Economy?
A second risk is that labor market tightness or tightness in other parts of the production chain might lead to higher inflation pressure than expected–the “revenge of the Phillips curve” scenario.16 As I mentioned, the FOMC carefully monitors a wide array of early indicators of inflation pressure to evaluate this risk. Wages and compensation data are one important source of information. These measures have picked up some recently, but in a way that is quite welcome. Specifically, the rise in wages is broadly consistent with observed rates of price inflation and labor productivity growth and therefore does not point to an overheating labor market. Further, higher wage growth alone need not be inflationary. The late 1990s episode of low unemployment saw wages rise faster than inflation plus productivity growth without an appreciable rise in inflation.

Despite what shows up in the aggregate wage and compensation data, however, I am sure that, like us, many of you are hearing widespread anecdotes about labor shortages and increasing bottlenecks in production. For example, as shown in figure 7, the words “shortage” and “bottleneck” are increasingly appearing in the Beige Book, the Federal Reserve’s report summarizing discussions with our business contacts around the country.17 The message we are hearing in our conversations is supported by a wide range of more conventional measures. For example, the survey of members of the National Federation of Independent Business finds firms increasingly reporting that job openings are hard to fill (figure 8). Further, these businesses now list “quality of labor” as their most important problem, as opposed to the more typical report of “poor sales.”

We review a wide variety of measures of this type, and these indicators show what I think most business people see: an economy operating with limited slack. Notice, however, that these measures are near levels that prevailed in the late 1990s or early 2000s, a period when core inflation remained under 2 percent.

While the late 1990s case proves that elevated values of these tightness measures do not automatically translate into rising inflation, a single episode provides only limited reassurance. Thus, the FOMC takes seriously the possibility that tight markets for labor or other inputs could provide greater upward pressure on inflation than in the baseline outlook. Our best estimates, however, suggest that so long as inflation expectations remain anchored, a modest steepening of the Phillips curve would be unlikely to cause a significant rise in inflation or demand a disruptive policy tightening.18 Once again, the key is the anchored expectations.

Is the Natural Rate of Unemployment Lower Than Expected?
A third risk–in this case an upside risk–is that the natural rate of unemployment could be even lower than current estimates. Some have argued that the Fed should be removing policy accommodation much more slowly, pushing the economy to see if the natural rate of unemployment is lower still.

Advocates of this view note that over the past several years of policy normalization, the economy has continued to strengthen and unemployment has fallen, but inflation has remained quiet. As I discussed in a recent speech, many analysts have accounted for the lack of rising inflation pressure by lowering their estimate of the natural rate.19 For example, since the start of 2016, the unemployment rate has fallen about 1 percentage point, and estimates of the natural rate from four well-known sources have fallen over that period between 0.3 percent and 0.7 percent (figure 9).

If the natural rate is now materially lower than we believe, that would imply less upward pressure on inflation–the flip side of the “revenge of the Phillips curve” risk. Our policy of gradual interest rate normalization represents the FOMC’s attempt to take both of these risks seriously. Removing accommodation too quickly could needlessly foreshorten the expansion. Moving too slowly could risk rising inflation and inflation expectations. Our path of gradually removing accommodation, while closely monitoring the economy, is designed to balance these risks.

In wrapping up this discussion of risks to the favorable outlook, I should emphasize that I have chosen to focus on three risks that are all associated with the Phillips curve. There are, of course, myriad other risks. To name just a few, we must consider the strength of economies abroad, the effects of ongoing trade disputes, and financial stability issues. I hope my discussion of three particular risks gives a sense of how we approach these issues.

Conclusion
Many of us have been looking back recently on the decade that has passed since the depths of the financial crisis. In light of that experience, I am glad to be able to stand here and say that the economy is strong, unemployment is near 50-year lows, and inflation is roughly at our 2 percent objective. The baseline outlook of forecasters inside and outside the Fed is for more of the same.

This historically rare pairing of steady, low inflation and very low unemployment is testament to the fact that we remain in extraordinary times. Our ongoing policy of gradual interest rate normalization reflects our efforts to balance the inevitable risks that come with extraordinary times, so as to extend the current expansion, while maintaining maximum employment and low and stable inflation.

via RSS https://ift.tt/2xSwOms Tyler Durden