Is the 'Knockout Game' a Hate Crime? Is It Even a Game?

Amrit
Marajh, the 28-year-old accused of sucker-punching Shmuel Perl, a
24-year-old Orthodox Jew, in the side of the head on Friday in the
Borough Park neigborhood of Brooklyn, has been
charged
with assault, which makes sense, and aggravated
harassment as a hate crime, which is harder to figure out. Leave
aside the question of whether a criminal should be punished extra
severely when he is motivated by bigotry. (He shouldn’t.)
According to
ABC News
, Perl said he “heard his alleged attackers daring each
other to punch him out minutes before one actually assaulted him.”
Hence the assault has been described as the latest example of “the
knockout game,” a pastime supposedly sweeping the nation in which
young assailants dare each other to knock out randomly selected
targets with a single punch. But if the victims are picked at
random, as the knockout game supposedly requires, can they also be
selected based on their ethnicity or religion? ABC does not
mention any anti-Semitic slurs or other evidence that Marajh
was looking for a Jew to attack, and neither do the accounts in

The New York Times
, the New York
Daily News
, or
The Jewish Press
. So why the hate crime charge? The
Daily News story suggests that Perl just happened to
be walking down the street at the wrong moment:

Amrit Marajh, 28, had just left a bar on McDonald Ave. on Friday
with four friends and was talking about boxing when the knockout
game came up, police sources said. 

“You can’t do that,” one member of the group said as they came
upon Shmuel Perl, 24, according to a source.

Marajh allegedly said, “Yes I can, I’ll do it to this guy right
now!” before punching Perl in the face, leaving him bruised.

Marajh’s lawyer, by contrast, told the Daily News “this
had nothing to do with the knockout game.” Also in dispute: whether
the knockout game is actually a thing. “Police officials in several
cities where such attacks have been reported said that the ‘game’
amounted to little more than an urban myth,” the
Times reports,
“and that the attacks in question might be nothing more than the
sort of random assaults that have always occurred.” For
example:

Much news coverage of reported knockout
attacks includes 2012 footage from a surveillance camera in
Pittsburgh of James Addlespurger, a high school teacher who
was 50, being swiftly struck to the ground by a young man
walking down an alleyway with some friends. Yet the Pittsburgh
police said the attacker insisted the assault was not part of any
organized “game.”

“This was just a random act of violence,” Police Commander Eric
Holmes said in a televised interview last year. “He stated that he
was just having a bad day that day.” The assailant saw Mr.
Addlespurger, the commander said, “and decided this was a course of
action he was going to take.”

Once such crimes are relabeled, of course, young thugs who are
inclined to attack people for no particular reason may start using
the new terminology, thereby retroactively validating it. If Marajh
and his friends really were talking about “the knockout game,” they
were probably discussing what they’d heard from news outlets hyping
this supposedly new trend.

from Hit & Run http://reason.com/blog/2013/11/25/is-the-knockout-game-a-hate-crime-is-it
via IFTTT

Is the ‘Knockout Game’ a Hate Crime? Is It Even a Game?

Amrit
Marajh, the 28-year-old accused of sucker-punching Shmuel Perl, a
24-year-old Orthodox Jew, in the side of the head on Friday in the
Borough Park neigborhood of Brooklyn, has been
charged
with assault, which makes sense, and aggravated
harassment as a hate crime, which is harder to figure out. Leave
aside the question of whether a criminal should be punished extra
severely when he is motivated by bigotry. (He shouldn’t.)
According to
ABC News
, Perl said he “heard his alleged attackers daring each
other to punch him out minutes before one actually assaulted him.”
Hence the assault has been described as the latest example of “the
knockout game,” a pastime supposedly sweeping the nation in which
young assailants dare each other to knock out randomly selected
targets with a single punch. But if the victims are picked at
random, as the knockout game supposedly requires, can they also be
selected based on their ethnicity or religion? ABC does not
mention any anti-Semitic slurs or other evidence that Marajh
was looking for a Jew to attack, and neither do the accounts in

The New York Times
, the New York
Daily News
, or
The Jewish Press
. So why the hate crime charge? The
Daily News story suggests that Perl just happened to
be walking down the street at the wrong moment:

Amrit Marajh, 28, had just left a bar on McDonald Ave. on Friday
with four friends and was talking about boxing when the knockout
game came up, police sources said. 

“You can’t do that,” one member of the group said as they came
upon Shmuel Perl, 24, according to a source.

Marajh allegedly said, “Yes I can, I’ll do it to this guy right
now!” before punching Perl in the face, leaving him bruised.

Marajh’s lawyer, by contrast, told the Daily News “this
had nothing to do with the knockout game.” Also in dispute: whether
the knockout game is actually a thing. “Police officials in several
cities where such attacks have been reported said that the ‘game’
amounted to little more than an urban myth,” the
Times reports,
“and that the attacks in question might be nothing more than the
sort of random assaults that have always occurred.” For
example:

Much news coverage of reported knockout
attacks includes 2012 footage from a surveillance camera in
Pittsburgh of James Addlespurger, a high school teacher who
was 50, being swiftly struck to the ground by a young man
walking down an alleyway with some friends. Yet the Pittsburgh
police said the attacker insisted the assault was not part of any
organized “game.”

“This was just a random act of violence,” Police Commander Eric
Holmes said in a televised interview last year. “He stated that he
was just having a bad day that day.” The assailant saw Mr.
Addlespurger, the commander said, “and decided this was a course of
action he was going to take.”

Once such crimes are relabeled, of course, young thugs who are
inclined to attack people for no particular reason may start using
the new terminology, thereby retroactively validating it. If Marajh
and his friends really were talking about “the knockout game,” they
were probably discussing what they’d heard from news outlets hyping
this supposedly new trend.

from Hit & Run http://reason.com/blog/2013/11/25/is-the-knockout-game-a-hate-crime-is-it
via IFTTT

Iron Chef Talks Food, Freedom, and the Future of American Cuisine

“What we’ve witnessed in the past 25 or 30 years is just
incredible,” says Iron Chef Geoffrey
Zakarian
 about the culinary revolution in America. “We’ve
birthed 30,000 or 40,000 restaurants. I used to go to Europe every
year to get experience [and ideas]. I don’t go to Europe anymore. I
go to Oregon, I go to Washington. I go to Louisiana, I go to Little
Rock. I go to Austin. I travel New York City. I don’t go to Europe
anymore.”

In a wide-ranging interview with Reason’s Nick Gillespie held at
The Lambs Club on November 5, the night before the
annual Reason Media
Awards
, Zakarian talks about why America’s cuisine has become a
hotbed of innovation and experimentation, how tough it is to make
it in the restaurant business under the best of circumstances, and
how food nannies are preventing even-better cuisine. “I can’t use
[raw milk] cheese without running afoul of the health inspectors,”
he says.

View this article.

from Hit & Run http://reason.com/blog/2013/11/25/iron-chef-talks-food-freedom-and-the-fut
via IFTTT

Bill Ackman's "Seven Hallmarks Of A Pyramid Scheme" Herbalife Takedown

We are used to hedge fund managers blindly making up “facts” to hide the reality that nothing else matters (most definitely not fundamentals) except the Fed’s balance sheet (in order to defend his 2-and-20 sapping performance). So it is ironic that Pershing Square’s Bill Ackman has added to his previous 342-slide PowerPoint presentation with the following 61 pages of his reality in the hope that market technicals (i.e. the weight of activist longs and shrinking float) and momentum will give way to his view that ‘these’ Herbalife’s fundamentals will eventually win. Good luck with that…

 

Here are his 7 Hallmarks of a Pyramid Scheme and the full Herbalife’s “Robin Hood In Reverse” presentation is found here:


    



via Zero Hedge http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/zerohedge/feed/~3/5AEN-oaluaU/story01.htm Tyler Durden

Bill Ackman’s “Seven Hallmarks Of A Pyramid Scheme” Herbalife Takedown

We are used to hedge fund managers blindly making up “facts” to hide the reality that nothing else matters (most definitely not fundamentals) except the Fed’s balance sheet (in order to defend his 2-and-20 sapping performance). So it is ironic that Pershing Square’s Bill Ackman has added to his previous 342-slide PowerPoint presentation with the following 61 pages of his reality in the hope that market technicals (i.e. the weight of activist longs and shrinking float) and momentum will give way to his view that ‘these’ Herbalife’s fundamentals will eventually win. Good luck with that…

 

Here are his 7 Hallmarks of a Pyramid Scheme and the full Herbalife’s “Robin Hood In Reverse” presentation is found here:


    



via Zero Hedge http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/zerohedge/feed/~3/5AEN-oaluaU/story01.htm Tyler Durden

Glutathione: Boost Your Health and Help Protect Yourself From Radiation

Glutathione is your body’s “master antioxidant”.

Every cell of your body contains glutathione. And glutathione makes any other antioxidant which you ingest more effective.

Low glutathione levels are associated with serious diseases such as cancer, Aids and diabetes.

As we age, our glutathione levels decline. Indeed, low glutathione levels may be associated with aging quickly:

Glutathione is also central to many other basic mechanisms in our body, such as immune response, blood transport and protein synthesis:

Numerous studies have shown that glutathione can help protect cells against radiation damage, including studies published in the following journals:

This is not entirely surprising, given that it’s well-documented that all antioxidants help to protect against damage from radiation.   Specifically, one of the main ways in which low-level ionizing radiation damages our bodies is by the creation of free radicals. (This 2-minute BBC video shows how damaging free radicals can be to your health.)

Columbia University explains the damaging effects of low-level radiation through free radical creation:

Some radiation experts argue that the creation of a lot of free radical creation is the most dangerous mechanism of low level ionizing radiation:

During exposure to low-level doses (LLD) of ionizing radiation (IR), the most of harmful effects are produced indirectly, through radiolysis of water and formation of reactive oxygen species (ROS). The antioxidant enzymes – superoxide dismutase (SOD): manganese SOD (MnSOD) and copper-zinc SOD (CuZnSOD), as well as glutathione (GSH), are the most important intracellular antioxidants in the metabolism of ROS. Overproduction of ROS challenges antioxidant enzymes.

We’ve previously told you how to get past the hype to find the foods that are highest in antioxidants.

But glutathione – as the “master antioxidant”, which is in every cell of your body – is probably the most important one to focus on.

Dr. Jimmy Gutman – a practicing physician, former Undergraduate Director and Residency Training Director of Emergency Medicine at McGill University in Montreal, Quebec, who has served on the Board of Directors of the Canadian Association of Emergency Physicians – claims:

Raising glutathione levels protects cells from damage from the most dangerous of free radicals, the hydroxyl-radical, is released when ionizing radiation hits us.

Note also that exposure to radiation depletes glutathione in your body.   You basically use up glutathione neutralizing the free radicals created by radiation. So it is important to keep your glutathione levels up when you are exposed to radiation.

How Can We Boost Glutathione Levels?

Despite the hype from the supplement industry, glutathione supplements don’t do anything.  Specifically, our stomach acid destroys glutathione … so you’ll be throwing money away if you buy supplemenets.

But you can eat foods that are high in the precursors to glutathione … and your body will use them to make more glutathione.

Specifically, 3 amino acides – cysteine, glycine and glutamate – are the precursors to glutathione production.

Protein-rich foods tends to be high in all 3. But heating or pasteurizing them destroys many of the glutathione-producing pro
perties.

For example, raw eggs and raw meat are high in cysteine, but cooking destroys the cysteine.   Most industrially-raised meat is of poor quality, and large-scale egg producers have been riddled with salmonella and other problems in recent years.

If you raise your own animals for meat or egg-laying hens, then you’ll know they’re safe.  Otherwise, it may be a little risky eating raw eggs or meat.

Raw milk is apparently very high in glutathione precursors.   But the USDA says that raw milk can be dangerous … and the police may go to some length to shut down raw milk producers.

Raw cruciferous vegetables (brocolli, cauliflower, brussel sprouts, cabbage, cress, and bok choy) are also a good source of cysteine.  But you would have to eat a lot of them … which would cause stomach distress in many people.

So what’s the answer?

Exercise boosts glutatione (and see this).  Lack of sleep can deplete glutathione.  So exercise and get enough rest.

Numerous scientific studies show that “undenatured whey protein” raises glutathione levels.  See this, this, this, this, this, and this.  (Whey protein is derived from milk or cheese, and “undenatured” just means that it is heated enough to kill bacteria … but not high enough to destroy the glutathione precursors.) You can buy it at most health food stores.

If you are a vegan – eating neither meat or dairy products – then you may want to make sure you get enough brown rice protein (because it’s high in the glutathione precursor cysteine).

Supplements available in health food stores – such as Alpha lipoic acid (and here), N-acetylcysteine, S-adenosyl-L-methionine, and the herb milk thistle (and see this) – have also been shown to boost glutathione levels.

For more information on glutathione from physicians – including additional tips for boosting glutathione levels – see this, this and this.

Postscript: Many companies are trying to sell various glutathione boosters. Some work, some don’t … and some do more harm than good. We don’t endorse any specific product.

Read this for more information on how to protect yourself from radiation.


    



via Zero Hedge http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/zerohedge/feed/~3/sBntFNffqHA/story01.htm George Washington

Guest Post: Madness… And Sanity

Submitted by Tim Price via Sovereign Man blog,

“In investing, what is comfortable is rarely profitable.” — Robert Arnott

Valuations still matter.

Assuming that one is ‘investing’ as opposed to ‘speculating’, initial valuation (i.e. the price you pay for the investment) remains the single most important characteristic of whatever one elects to buy.

And at the risk of sounding like a broken record, “initial valuation” in the US stock market is at a level consistent with very disappointing subsequent returns, if the history of the last 130 years is any guide.

Without fail, every time the US market has traded on a cyclically-adjusted P/E (CAPE) ratio of 24 or higher over the past 130 years, it has been followed by a roughly 20 year bear market.

The evidence for the prosecution is clear, especially for the peak years 1901, 1929, 1966 and 2000. And 2013? The CAPE ratio is more than 25 today.

But there is the stock market, and then there are individual stocks. We have no interest in the former, but plenty of interest in the opportunity set of the latter.

We’re just not that interested in the US market, given general valuation concerns, and the malign role of Fed policy in distorting the prices of everything. As purists and unashamed value investors, we have plenty of other fish to fry.

Probably the biggest of those fish is that giant part of the world economy known as Asia. The chart below shows the anticipated growth in numbers of the middle class throughout the world over the next two decades.

AsiaGrowth Madness, and sanity

The solid green circle is the current middle class population (or as at 2009 to be precise); the wider blue-fringed circle represents the forecast size of this population in 20 years’ time.

The OECD definition of middle class is those households with daily per capita expenditures of between $10 and $100 in purchasing power parity terms.

Note that in the US and Europe, the size of the middle class is barely expected to change over the next two decades. The stand-out area is obvious: the emerging middle class in Asia is forecast to explode, from roughly 500 million to some 3 billion people.

In equity investing, the combination of a compelling secular growth story and compellingly attractive valuations is a very rare thing, the sort of investment opportunity that one might only see once or twice in a generation, if that.

But it exists, here in Asia, today. Once again, however, we have to abandon conventional financial thinking in order to exploit it.

Asian personal consumption between 2007 and 2012 – while the West was suffering from a little localised financial crisis – grew by 5% to 10% per annum. Industries likely to benefit from sustained growth in domestic consumption include food and beverages, clothes, cars, and insurance.

But the index composition of Asian equity index benchmarks leaves much to be desired.

Of the 10 largest companies in the MSCI Asia ex-Japan index, three are low margin exporters in Korea and Taiwan, one is a low margin Chinese telecoms business, three are state-run Chinese banks, one is an inefficient Chinese oil and gas producer, and one is an expensive Chinese internet business.

That doesn’t leave much for value investors to go on.

Asian equity funds more generally, tending to be index-trackers, are heavy in Chinese stocks of indeterminate value and clunky ‘old Asia’ exporters with far too much research coverage.

Or one can ignore index composition (‘yesterday’s winners’) entirely and focus instead on ‘best in breed’ businesses throughout the region on an unconstrained basis– especially those with favorable returns on equity, strong balance sheets, and low valuations.

As Greg Fisher of Adepa Asset Management wrote, amid a world of worries, “keeping the discipline of holding lowly valued, under-owned and unleveraged companies is likely to continue to protect our capital and earn us both income and capital appreciation over the longer term.”

Or to put it more plainly, and in the words of Warren Buffett, “price is what you pay; value is what you get.”

US stocks may be expensive, but you can get better economic fundamentals and cheaper valuations selectively throughout Asia.

And as insurance against the sort of disorderly currency moves that seem to be almost inevitable courtesy of so many central banks behaving badly, we still maintain you can’t do better over the medium term than gold.


    



via Zero Hedge http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/zerohedge/feed/~3/gJqCaZfs9j8/story01.htm Tyler Durden

Returning 2706% In The Past 40 Years, The Best Performing "Yellow" Asset Is…

Monopolistic supply? Thriving wealth-effect-driven demand?

 

As we noted previously,

Medallions – essentially the right to operate a for-hail taxi in New York City – now trade for as much as $1.3 million, an all-time record.   

 

Part of this dynamic is fixed supply – there are just 13,336 medallions available for a city of 8.3 million people.  There is also a macroeconomic point, with a stronger NYC economy for those inhabitants who can afford the service.  The more surprising observation, however, is that new technology in the form of in-car credit card machines and more recently smartphone hailing apps both materially increase the value of owning a medallion.  In a world where every technology is deemed “Disruptive”, here’s a case where the status quo has actually reaped much of the reward.

 

Via ConvergEx's Nick Colas,

Here’s a news flash for everyone who thinks Elon Musk Is the preeminent automotive visionary of our generation: New York City was running electric taxicabs in the 1890s, a decade before Henry Ford’s Model T ever turned a wheel on America’s roads.  A financial crisis in 1907 put a predictable dent in consumer demand for NYC cars-for-hire, and the rise of the internal combustion engine in the 1910s and 1920s eventually did away with the battery-powered cab in Gotham.  By the 1930s the city actually had a glut of taxis, by some accounts as many as 30,000 plying the streets for fares in a Depression-era New York.

To clean up the oversupply of increasingly poorly maintained cabs with drivers desperate to make ends meet in a lousy economy, Mayor Fiorello La Guardia signed something called the Haas Act, which limited the number of taxis to 16,900.  Over the years this cap dwindled to 11,787, even as the city’s population grew.  The basic rules behind this permit, called a “Medallion”, remain largely unchanged from La Guardia’s day, and include:

  • The license to own and operate a taxicab.
  • The ownership of the medallion may be sold or pledged as collateral for a loan.
  • The exclusive right to accept street hails.
  • Fares regulated and authorized by the NYC Taxi and Limousine Commission.
  • Owners of medallions must be US citizens or permanent residents
  • Independent medallion owners must operate their cab 210 nine-hour shifts a year
  • Corporate owners must operate their cabs 24/7
  • Inspections of the vehicle occur every 4 months
  • Medallions sales are subject to a 5% transfer tax

As the number of medallions available is controlled by this process – there are only 13,336 on the streets today – they are quite valuable.  Since both individual and corporate owners can sell their medallions at will, there is a ready market for these licenses.  We’ve included several charts and tables with historical price information immediately after this note, but here are the highlights:

 
 

Owning a medallion has been a winning trade that even the NY hedge fund managers who likely take several cab trips a day would covet.  At the beginning of the Financial Crisis in January 2007, an “Individual” medallion went for $414,000 and a “Corporate” version for $522,000.  Now, the numbers are $1.05 million (July 2013 “Individual”) and $1.32 million (last trade for a “Corporate” medallion, May 2013).  That is an average return of 153% over the last six and a half years. 

 

The longer term track record for medallions is equally impressive – they went for just $140,000 or so in 1993 – but teasing out the actual reasons for these eye-popping returns takes some work.  Remember that the pricing economics of taxi cab operation – and therefore the value of owning a medallion – is controlled by regulation.  You can only charge so much per mile and for wait time.

 

We went back to 1948 to see if these statutory fares explained the increasing value of a medallion.  In that year, for example, a typical cab ride of 1.5 miles with 5 minutes of waiting time at lights would cost $0.63 and the cost of a medallion was $2,500.   It would therefore have taken the average medallion owner about 4,000 trips to pay for his license.  Fast forward to 1964, and this number rose to almost 30,000 trips because fare increases did not keep pace with medallion inflation.

 

 

The good news for the medallion owner of the 1960s-1990s was that this 30,000 trip breakeven declined to about 15,000 during the difficult period of the 1970s in the city and did not breach the 30,000 mark again until 1997.  Fare increases, in other words, offset the ever rising costs of a medallion.  Gas prices also play a role in taxi cab profitability, of course, but it is worth noting (and is clear from our data) that medallion prices did not decline as oil prices rose from 1973 to the present day.

 

Taxi medallion economics have seen a breakout since the early 2000s, as evidenced by our breakeven analysis based on current fare schedules.  It now takes almost 83,000 “Typical” 1.5 mile trips for an “Individual” medallion owner to break even, up from 42,700 in 2004.  For the corporate owner, those numbers rise to 115,600 – up from 48,600 nine years ago.

Now, if you’ve ever had the chance to meet a medallion owner, you know that these are very tough people when it comes to making money.  They know their numbers cold and aren’t shy about expressing their point of view.  In short, they make the typical Wall Streeter look like slightly pouty 8 year old.   Add to this fact the realization that NYC plans to auction off 2,000 new medallions this year AND introduce a new cheap ($1,500) livery license for the outer boroughs and northern Manhattan, and the fundamentals look pretty bewildering.

Here are a few thoughts on the “Mystery of the Million Dollar Medallion”:

 
 

Pricing for a cab ride may be regulated, but nothing says New Yorkers have to take the trip.  One interpretation of the breakout in medallion prices is that New York’s affluent classes have had their own step-up in income and/or wealth and are more often taking cabs than even in the 1990s.  A wrinkle on this explanation would be that as more of
Manhattan and parts of Brooklyn go through gentrification, the total population of potential cab customers increases.  This further helps keep the 13,336 medallions busy through the day.  A survey from the mid 2000s showed that most cab rides occurred during the morning commute and were generally to midtown Manhattan from the Upper East and West Side.  As the areas where affluent New Yorker live and work expand, so does their usage of yellow cabs.

 

The increase in medallion prices to nose-bleed levels is, therefore, a sign that the New York economy is extremely strong at least among the top 20% of the population by income.  Remember that if 14,000 wealthy New Yorkers all stuck their hands up at the same time on their corner, over 500 of them would have to grab a MetroCard to get to work.  And the city has 8.3 million total inhabitants.

 

The introduction of in-car credit card processing has been a boon to cab drivers tips.  According to one analysis done in 2009, cash-only tips used to run 10% of the fare.  Since the credit card options for driver tips only offer choices of 20% or more, the introduction of these machines over the last few years has meant higher per-trip revenues for the driver.  And since part of the value of a medallion is essentially the right to collect these tips, it makes sense that drivers would pay medallion owners more over time.

 

Perhaps the most interesting wild card for the value of a NYC taxi medallion is the burgeoning technology of smartphone taxi applications like Hailo, Uber, Lyft and others.  These do pretty much what you’d expect – find you a nearby cab based with information from your geolocated phone.  This could easily improve cab utilization in New York quite dramatically, justifying higher medallion prices.  The first usage data from such apps has just come out in the past few weeks, and the results are lukewarm at best.  It is, however, early days. 

What I find most interesting about this exercise is the fact that technology – credit cards and smartphone apps – has served to enhance the value of established status quo rather than its customary role of “Disruptor”.  To understand why, remember who owns the right to issue a medallion: the New York City government.  The current plans to issue 2,000 more medallions could net the still cash-strapped city something like $2 billion over the next few years.  And they control the laws about who can – and can’t – pick up a fare in New York.  Think they are going to let a “Disruptive technology” alter their existing and highly lucrative model?

If so, I have a bridge in Brooklyn I would like to sell you.  All we need to do is find a taxi to take us there. 


    



via Zero Hedge http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/zerohedge/feed/~3/WTAKNA0xHGs/story01.htm Tyler Durden

Returning 2706% In The Past 40 Years, The Best Performing “Yellow” Asset Is…

Monopolistic supply? Thriving wealth-effect-driven demand?

 

As we noted previously,

Medallions – essentially the right to operate a for-hail taxi in New York City – now trade for as much as $1.3 million, an all-time record.   

 

Part of this dynamic is fixed supply – there are just 13,336 medallions available for a city of 8.3 million people.  There is also a macroeconomic point, with a stronger NYC economy for those inhabitants who can afford the service.  The more surprising observation, however, is that new technology in the form of in-car credit card machines and more recently smartphone hailing apps both materially increase the value of owning a medallion.  In a world where every technology is deemed “Disruptive”, here’s a case where the status quo has actually reaped much of the reward.

 

Via ConvergEx's Nick Colas,

Here’s a news flash for everyone who thinks Elon Musk Is the preeminent automotive visionary of our generation: New York City was running electric taxicabs in the 1890s, a decade before Henry Ford’s Model T ever turned a wheel on America’s roads.  A financial crisis in 1907 put a predictable dent in consumer demand for NYC cars-for-hire, and the rise of the internal combustion engine in the 1910s and 1920s eventually did away with the battery-powered cab in Gotham.  By the 1930s the city actually had a glut of taxis, by some accounts as many as 30,000 plying the streets for fares in a Depression-era New York.

To clean up the oversupply of increasingly poorly maintained cabs with drivers desperate to make ends meet in a lousy economy, Mayor Fiorello La Guardia signed something called the Haas Act, which limited the number of taxis to 16,900.  Over the years this cap dwindled to 11,787, even as the city’s population grew.  The basic rules behind this permit, called a “Medallion”, remain largely unchanged from La Guardia’s day, and include:

  • The license to own and operate a taxicab.
  • The ownership of the medallion may be sold or pledged as collateral for a loan.
  • The exclusive right to accept street hails.
  • Fares regulated and authorized by the NYC Taxi and Limousine Commission.
  • Owners of medallions must be US citizens or permanent residents
  • Independent medallion owners must operate their cab 210 nine-hour shifts a year
  • Corporate owners must operate their cabs 24/7
  • Inspections of the vehicle occur every 4 months
  • Medallions sales are subject to a 5% transfer tax

As the number of medallions available is controlled by this process – there are only 13,336 on the streets today – they are quite valuable.  Since both individual and corporate owners can sell their medallions at will, there is a ready market for these licenses.  We’ve included several charts and tables with historical price information immediately after this note, but here are the highlights:

 
 

Owning a medallion has been a winning trade that even the NY hedge fund managers who likely take several cab trips a day would covet.  At the beginning of the Financial Crisis in January 2007, an “Individual” medallion went for $414,000 and a “Corporate” version for $522,000.  Now, the numbers are $1.05 million (July 2013 “Individual”) and $1.32 million (last trade for a “Corporate” medallion, May 2013).  That is an average return of 153% over the last six and a half years. 

 

The longer term track record for medallions is equally impressive – they went for just $140,000 or so in 1993 – but teasing out the actual reasons for these eye-popping returns takes some work.  Remember that the pricing economics of taxi cab operation – and therefore the value of owning a medallion – is controlled by regulation.  You can only charge so much per mile and for wait time.

 

We went back to 1948 to see if these statutory fares explained the increasing value of a medallion.  In that year, for example, a typical cab ride of 1.5 miles with 5 minutes of waiting time at lights would cost $0.63 and the cost of a medallion was $2,500.   It would therefore have taken the average medallion owner about 4,000 trips to pay for his license.  Fast forward to 1964, and this number rose to almost 30,000 trips because fare increases did not keep pace with medallion inflation.

 

 

The good news for the medallion owner of the 1960s-1990s was that this 30,000 trip breakeven declined to about 15,000 during the difficult period of the 1970s in the city and did not breach the 30,000 mark again until 1997.  Fare increases, in other words, offset the ever rising costs of a medallion.  Gas prices also play a role in taxi cab profitability, of course, but it is worth noting (and is clear from our data) that medallion prices did not decline as oil prices rose from 1973 to the present day.

 

Taxi medallion economics have seen a breakout since the early 2000s, as evidenced by our breakeven analysis based on current fare schedules.  It now takes almost 83,000 “Typical” 1.5 mile trips for an “Individual” medallion owner to break even, up from 42,700 in 2004.  For the corporate owner, those numbers rise to 115,600 – up from 48,600 nine years ago.

Now, if you’ve ever had the chance to meet a medallion owner, you know that these are very tough people when it comes to making money.  They know their numbers cold and aren’t shy about expressing their point of view.  In short, they make the typical Wall Streeter look like slightly pouty 8 year old.   Add to this fact the realization that NYC plans to auction off 2,000 new medallions this year AND introduce a new cheap ($1,500) livery license for the outer boroughs and northern Manhattan, and the fundamentals look pretty bewildering.

Here are a few thoughts on the “Mystery of the Million Dollar Medallion”:

 
 

Pricing for a cab ride may be regulated, but nothing says New Yorkers have to take the trip.  One interpretation of the breakout in medallion prices is that New York’s affluent classes have had their own step-up in income and/or wealth and are more often taking cabs than even in the 1990s.  A wrinkle on this explanation would be that as more of Manhattan and parts of Brooklyn go through gentrification, the total population of potential cab customers increases.  This further helps keep the 13,336 medallions busy through the day.  A survey from the mid 2000s showed that most cab rides occurred during the morning commute and were generally to midtown Manhattan from the Upper East and West Side.  As the areas where affluent New Yorker live and work expand, so does their usage of yellow cabs.

 

The increase in medallion prices to nose-bleed levels is, therefore, a sign that the New York economy is extremely strong at least among the top 20% of the population by income.  Remember that if 14,000 wealthy New Yorkers all stuck their hands up at the same time on their corner, over 500 of them would have to grab a MetroCard to get to work.  And the city has 8.3 million total inhabitants.

 

The introduction of in-car credit card processing has been a boon to cab drivers tips.  According to one analysis done in 2009, cash-only tips used to run 10% of the fare.  Since the credit card options for driver tips only offer choices of 20% or more, the introduction of these machines over the last few years has meant higher per-trip revenues for the driver.  And since part of the value of a medallion is essentially the right to collect these tips, it makes sense that drivers would pay medallion owners more over time.

 

Perhaps the most interesting wild card for the value of a NYC taxi medallion is the burgeoning technology of smartphone taxi applications like Hailo, Uber, Lyft and others.  These do pretty much what you’d expect – find you a nearby cab based with information from your geolocated phone.  This could easily improve cab utilization in New York quite dramatically, justifying higher medallion prices.  The first usage data from such apps has just come out in the past few weeks, and the results are lukewarm at best.  It is, however, early days. 

What I find most interesting about this exercise is the fact that technology – credit cards and smartphone apps – has served to enhance the value of established status quo rather than its customary role of “Disruptor”.  To understand why, remember who owns the right to issue a medallion: the New York City government.  The current plans to issue 2,000 more medallions could net the still cash-strapped city something like $2 billion over the next few years.  And they control the laws about who can – and can’t – pick up a fare in New York.  Think they are going to let a “Disruptive technology” alter their existing and highly lucrative model?

If so, I have a bridge in Brooklyn I would like to sell you.  All we need to do is find a taxi to take us there. 


    



via Zero Hedge http://feedproxy.google.com/~r/zerohedge/feed/~3/WTAKNA0xHGs/story01.htm Tyler Durden

Senators Still Pushing Iran Sanctions Even With an Actual Deal on the Table, Reluctant Warmongers Want War

head strong, dead wrong?Negotiators from Iran and Germany, France, and
England (the E3), and later also the US, Russia, and China (the
E3+3, or P5+1) have been working on-and-off for more than seven
years on a deal about Iran’s nuclear program, which the West
insists is actually about acquiring nuclear weapons. After a deal
appeared just out of reach in a round of negotiations earlier this
month, some US senators, most notably Bob Menendez, the Democrat
chair of the Senate Foreign Relations Committee, pushed for more
sanctions, to show the Iranians the US was not as interested as
they were in reaching a deal,
a silly argument
of which Secretary of State John Kerry was
nevertheless
unable to disabuse
senators interested in a more hostile policy
toward Iran.

This weekend, the latest round of talks actually produced a
deal, with Iran agreeing within the first six months to stop
enriching uranium beyond 5 percent, and to downgrade or eliminate
its uranium stockpile that’s at near 20 percent enrichment. In
exchange, the Western powers agree to a limited lifting of
sanctions. As the White House explains, “the overwhelming majority
of the sanctions regime, including the key oil, banking, and
financial sanctions architecture, remains in place.” That’s not
enough for Senate hawks, Democrat and Republican, who are
starting to push
, again, for more sanctions. This time,
Menendez wants to work on sanctions legislation that somewhat
incorporates the recently reached deal—it would “provide for a six
month window to reach a final agreement before imposing new
sanctions on Iran, but will at the same time be immediately
available should the talks falter or Iran fail to implement or
breach the interim agreement.” Armchair (dais?) tough guy to the
last.

Republicans, even more eager to show voters they’re tougher than
the president on Iran. Marco Rubio,
for example
, sees an “even more urgent need for Congress to
increase sanctions until Iran completely abandons its enrichment
and reprocessing capabilities.” Establishment Republicans aren’t
just interested in showing their more headstrong than President
Obama, they may also be
trying to isolate non-interventionists in their own party
, most
notably Kentucky senator and likely future presidential candidate
Rand Paul.

It’s a bizarre move by establishment Republicans, and Democrats.
As recently as late September, 75 percent of Americans
favored
direct negotiations with Iran over the nuclear issue
(even as Obama’s poll numbers have plummeted). That number included
a full 68 percent of Republicans. The argument that direct
negotiations need sanctions to work is specious, as I made the case

earlier this month
. Attempts by senators to jump the gun on
sanctions now, as talks are moving forward, destroy the good faith
 it was so difficult for negotiators on all sides to build.
Americans, too, are weary of war, something the White House has not
shied away from
pointing out
would be the direction increased sanctions and
failed talks would push US policy toward.

this closeBill
Kristol takes issue with this, calling it a “smear” to identify
politicians pushing policies that would lead to war as “reckless
warmongers.”  He follows this, in typical embellished fashion
(the battle of Gettysburg makes an appearance), by noting Israeli
prime minister Benjamin Netanyahu would have the “burden of
history” hanging over him as he decides whether to launch military
action to “thwart” Iran’s nuclear ambitions. Polling last year

showed
fewer than 20 percent of Israelis supporting a
unilateral strike. As negotiations have begun to show progress, and
Netanyahu has continued to push the argument that the US is wrong
to negotiate with Iran in the fashion it has, those numbers have
reversed. One poll earlier this month
showed
52 percent of Israelis now supporting a solo strike now,
with 65 percent
opposing
the ongoing talks with Iran. Israeli columnist Shlomi
Eldar questions the depth of Israeli support for war with Iran.
“Israelis should be asked if they are for or against an attack in
Iran that could develop into a war with hundreds of casualties,” he

writes in Al Monitor
. “Would 65% of Israelis still vote in
favor? I doubt it.” The argument of pro-war supporters in Israel,
the US, and everywhere in between hinges on how close Iran is to
developing a nuclear weapon (Years! Months!), even though
intelligence analysts have been predicting Iran being close to the
development of a nuclear weapon
since at least the late 1990s
. Instead of the burdens of
history, self-professed reluctant warmongers should consider the
burdens of proof.

from Hit & Run http://reason.com/blog/2013/11/25/senators-still-pushing-sanctions-even-wi
via IFTTT