Senate Will Vote To Avert Shutdown; Pelosi Reschedules Infrastructure Vote After Progressives Refuse To Budge

Senate Will Vote To Avert Shutdown; Pelosi Reschedules Infrastructure Vote After Progressives Refuse To Budge

As expected, the Senate is set to kick the can down the road on funding the government past a Thursday night deadline. According to Senate Majority Leader Chuck Schumer (D-NY), the chamber will vote today or tomorrow on a “clean” continuing resolution (CR) which will avert a shutdown until December 3.

That said, as Goldman’s Alec Phillips notes, by separating the continuing resolution from a debt ceiling vote, Democrats are giving up leverage in the hopes of passing both at the same time.

The decision to set the CR deadline for Dec. 3 lowers the risks around the debt limit slightly compared to the alternative, which would have been a mid-Oct. deadline. In light of the Treasury’s projection that the debt limit will need to be raised by Oct. 18, the two deadlines are now separate and congressional Democrats cannot use the next spending deadline to try to force a bipartisan debt vote to suspend the debt limit. 

Of note, while Treasury Secretary Janet Yellen predicted the ‘drop-dead’ date on the debt ceiling will be October 18, the Congressional Budget Office on Wednesday estimated it would most likely happen towards the end of October, or early November.

Pelosi punts

Meanwhile in the House, Speaker Nancy Pelosi (D-CA) is expected to cancel a Thursday vote on the $1 trillion bipartisan infrastructure plan (BIF), because she doesn’t have the votes to pass it. According to The Hill, more than two-dozen progressive Democrats are planning to vote “no” on the BIF because it’s been separated from the $3.5  trillion spending package.

“They will not pass it on Thursday. Enough of the House members understand that they would be gutting the Build Back Better agenda,” one Democratic lawmaker told the outlet, adding “Nancy will pull it. We’re pretty sure she won’t put it up for a vote. She’ll meet with the moderates and she’ll say, ‘Listen, I don’t put these things up when the votes aren’t there. It doesn’t help your cause to see it fail, it doesn’t help the president to see it fail.”

Pelosi had promised the bill would receive a vote on Monday and then delayed the vote to Thursday. 

On Wednesday, she said the vote was still scheduled but acknowledged that as Speaker, she could shift the schedule. She also reiterated that she will not bring a bill to the floor that does not have the votes to pass.

Pelosi said Wednesday that she won’t move one bill without the other.

“We’re doing it simultaneously,” she said.

Progressives have been pressing for two centrist Democratic senators, Joe Manchin (W.Va.) and Kyrsten Sinema (Ariz.), to specify what they can support in the larger social spending plan, which Democrats want to move under budget reconciliation rules. -The Hill

The Progressive pushback was backed by Senate Budget Chairman Bernie Sanders (I-VT), who warned progressives in a Tuesday conference call that they will completely lose their leverage if they let the $1 trillion package pass.

“There was an agreement in terms of a dual track and that I’m not happy to see that agreement reneged on, and second of all that we’ll lose our leverage in passing a strong reconciliation bill here if they were to pass the infrastructure bill,” said Sanders to House progressives.

Tyler Durden
Wed, 09/29/2021 – 14:27

via ZeroHedge News https://ift.tt/3ATLaBB Tyler Durden

Biden Agrees With Obama That “Open Borders Are Unsustainable”: Psaki

Biden Agrees With Obama That “Open Borders Are Unsustainable”: Psaki

In an interview with ABC‘s “Good Morning America” which aired Tuesday, former President Barack Obama said that the crisis at the border in Del Rio, Texas is “heartbreaking,” and that comprehensive immigration reform is needed to fix “a system that, overall, is dysfunctional.”

“It’s no secret that we don’t have that. It’s the reason I proposed comprehensive immigration reform. It’s the reason Joe Biden proposed it during his administration, and it’s something that is long overdue,” said Obama.

Obama said that the crisis in Del Rio “is a painful reminder that we don’t have this right yet and we’ve got more work to do.”

“As big-hearted as he is, nobody understands that better than Joe Biden,” Obama added. “And the question is now: Are we gonna get serious about dealing with this problem in a systemic way, as opposed to these one-offs where we’re constantly reacting to emergencies? And I think that that’s something that every American should wanna put an end to.” -ABC News

“Immigration is tough. It always has been because, on the one hand, I think we are naturally a people that wants to help others. And we see tragedy and hardship and families that are desperately trying to get here so that their kids are safe, and they’re in some cases fleeing violence or catastrophe,” Obama continued. “At the same time, we’re a nation state. We have borders. The idea that we can just have open borders is something that … as a practical matter, is unsustainable.”

Hilariously, ABC cut Obama’s comments out of footage of the interview – only mentioning it in the 12th paragraph of their accompanying article.

Psaki gets snarky (shocker!)

When asked on Wednesday if Biden agreed with Obama, specifically – “Does President Biden agree with President Obama that ‘open borders’ is unsustainable?”

Psaki shot back “We don’t have open borders. So yes, he agrees.

Psaki’s comments come after 30,000 migrants crossed the open Rio Grande river into Del Rio, Texas over a two-week period, with as many as 14,000 migrants camped under the city’s International Bridge. 

On Sunday, Homeland Security secretary Alejandro Mayorkas said that around 12,000 of those migrants were released into the US (20% of which have Covid, apparently).

Tyler Durden
Wed, 09/29/2021 – 14:20

via ZeroHedge News https://ift.tt/3meAvvb Tyler Durden

FTC Drills Alabama Licensing Board for Anti-competitive Scheme Targeting Teledentistry


2 (1)

Alabama’s dental regulators have agreed to drop an anti-competitive scheme that blocked teledentistry services in the state.

As part of a consent agreement announced Tuesday, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) said the Board of Dental Examiners of Alabama would stop enforcing rules that limited “consumer choice and excluded new providers” offering braces and other teeth alignment services.

Those rules were crafted in 2017, after startups like SmileDirectClub began operating in Alabama. According to the FTC, the board took steps to stop the expansion of “firms providing clear aligners in Alabama through a teledentistry model” by amending its rules to ban dental hygienists and other medical professionals from performing the scans that are necessary to ensure proper fitting of the alignment devices. Previously, licensed dentists were allowed to supervise the scans from a remote location. Under the new rules, they would have to be on-site when the scans were done.

Over the next two years, the board delivered cease-and-desist letters to providers who offered those services without on-site licensed dentists.

“The actions of the Dental Board have deprived consumers in Alabama of low-price, convenient options for teeth alignment treatment without any legitimate justification or defense,” the FTC argued in a complaint against the board. Those actions, the commission says, “unreasonably restrained competition” and violated federal law.

The case is a sequel to the FTC’s 2015 victory at the U.S. Supreme Court in a case challenging anti-competitive behavior by a similar board in North Carolina. In that instance, the North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners sent cease-and-desist letters to kiosks offering teeth whitening services. The practice of whitening teeth, the board declared, could only be done by licensed dentists.

When that case ended up before the U.S. Supreme Court, the justices ruled that licensing boards controlled by a majority of “active market participants” could not make deliberately anti-competitive rules—unless those boards were “actively supervised” by some other element of state government. As a result of that ruling, licensing boards enforcing anticompetitive rules could be sued for violating federal antitrust laws.

The ruling opened up a new legal avenue for challenging overbearing licensing boards that limit economic opportunities by blocking competition in certain professional fields. It was a resounding defeat for overreaching state regulation and “the culmination of 15 years of effort” Maureen Ohlhausen, then-chair of the FTC, told Reason shortly after the ruling.

That case laid the groundwork for the more recent actions in Alabama, where six of the board’s seven members are required by law to be licensed, actively practicing dentists. And the board’s actions are not “reviewed or approved by any neutral state officials with the power to veto or modify” its decisions, the FTC found.

Under the terms of the consent agreement struck between the FTC and the Alabama dental board, the board does not admit to violating any laws or to engaging in the alleged anti-competitive behavior. But, going forward, the board has agreed to stop requiring on-site supervision by licensed dentists of the alignment scans necessary for teledentistry services.

That should give residents of Alabama—some 1.8 million of whom live in areas deemed to have a shortage of dental professionals and could clearly benefit from a greater supply of teledentistry services—something to smile about.

from Latest – Reason.com https://ift.tt/3zTIS47
via IFTTT

FTC Drills Alabama Licensing Board for Anti-competitive Scheme Targeting Teledentistry


2 (1)

Alabama’s dental regulators have agreed to drop an anti-competitive scheme that blocked teledentistry services in the state.

As part of a consent agreement announced Tuesday, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) said the Board of Dental Examiners of Alabama would stop enforcing rules that limited “consumer choice and excluded new providers” offering braces and other teeth alignment services.

Those rules were crafted in 2017, after startups like SmileDirectClub began operating in Alabama. According to the FTC, the board took steps to stop the expansion of “firms providing clear aligners in Alabama through a teledentistry model” by amending its rules to ban dental hygienists and other medical professionals from performing the scans that are necessary to ensure proper fitting of the alignment devices. Previously, licensed dentists were allowed to supervise the scans from a remote location. Under the new rules, they would have to be on-site when the scans were done.

Over the next two years, the board delivered cease-and-desist letters to providers who offered those services without on-site licensed dentists.

“The actions of the Dental Board have deprived consumers in Alabama of low-price, convenient options for teeth alignment treatment without any legitimate justification or defense,” the FTC argued in a complaint against the board. Those actions, the commission says, “unreasonably restrained competition” and violated federal law.

The case is a sequel to the FTC’s 2015 victory at the U.S. Supreme Court in a case challenging anti-competitive behavior by a similar board in North Carolina. In that instance, the North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners sent cease-and-desist letters to kiosks offering teeth whitening services. The practice of whitening teeth, the board declared, could only be done by licensed dentists.

When that case ended up before the U.S. Supreme Court, the justices ruled that licensing boards controlled by a majority of “active market participants” could not make deliberately anti-competitive rules—unless those boards were “actively supervised” by some other element of state government. As a result of that ruling, licensing boards enforcing anticompetitive rules could be sued for violating federal antitrust laws.

The ruling opened up a new legal avenue for challenging overbearing licensing boards that limit economic opportunities by blocking competition in certain professional fields. It was a resounding defeat for overreaching state regulation and “the culmination of 15 years of effort” Maureen Ohlhausen, then-chair of the FTC, told Reason shortly after the ruling.

That case laid the groundwork for the more recent actions in Alabama, where six of the board’s seven members are required by law to be licensed, actively practicing dentists. And the board’s actions are not “reviewed or approved by any neutral state officials with the power to veto or modify” its decisions, the FTC found.

Under the terms of the consent agreement struck between the FTC and the Alabama dental board, the board does not admit to violating any laws or to engaging in the alleged anti-competitive behavior. But, going forward, the board has agreed to stop requiring on-site supervision by licensed dentists of the alignment scans necessary for teledentistry services.

That should give residents of Alabama—some 1.8 million of whom live in areas deemed to have a shortage of dental professionals and could clearly benefit from a greater supply of teledentistry services—something to smile about.

from Latest – Reason.com https://ift.tt/3zTIS47
via IFTTT

“Declaration Of Media War”: Russia Threatens Total Ban On YouTube After Major Channels Deleted

“Declaration Of Media War”: Russia Threatens Total Ban On YouTube After Major Channels Deleted

The Kremlin on Wednesday slammed YouTube for unwarranted “censorship” and “media obstruction” after the day prior the Google-owned video hosting platform suddenly blocked two German RT channels, including RT Deutsch which was competing for traffic with major German news and politics channels. YouTube said the Russian state media channels had breached its Covid ‘disinformation’ policies.

At the time it was blocked RT Deutsch had over 600,000 subscribers and was approaching 600 million total views, according to Russian media reports. “Of course, there are signs that Russian laws have been violated, violated very rudely, as this, of course, is associated with censorship, and with obstruction of the media information dissemination,” Kremlin spokesman Dmitry Peskov said.

Image source: SNA/Der Spiegel 

“If our supervisory authorities come to the conclusion that this is, indeed, a violation of our legislation, then, of course, we cannot, we should not exclude the possibility of taking measures to force this platform to comply with our laws,” he added. 

A separate Foreign Ministry statement called it “outright information aggression” – and RT’s editor-in-chief Margarita Simonyan called the ban a “real media war declared by the state of Germany to the state of Russia” in a social media post.

However, the German government was quick to distance itself from Facebook’s ban, saying it didn’t have anything to do with the order. “They were not implemented by the German government,” a German official said

“This is a YouTube’s decision against RT and, I believe, one more channel, which is based on YouTube rules. We are taking note of this. Obviously, the affected channels have opportunities to oppose this,” cabinet spokesman Steffen Seibert told reporters at a briefing.

Moscow was quick to hit back at parent company Google, according to Politico threatening to block the platform altogether from the Russian Federation:

Russian authorities threatened to block YouTube on Wednesday, a day after RT’s German-language channels were deleted with Google’s video platform saying the Russian state-backed broadcaster had breached its COVID-19 information policy.

This morning, Roskomnadzor, the Russian government’s media watchdog, threatened to block YouTube in Russia if it didn’t restore the banned channelsRBC news reported.

It’s not the first time that such a threat has been made, which also recently included Twitter. The Kremlin has in the past charged US-based social media platforms with violating obscenity laws. More recently Russian officials have denounced ‘political interference’ based on the platforms advancing pro-Navalny groups and other opposition content. 

On Wednesday, a Russian court moved to take concrete action against Google for the Germany ban, slapping it with a 6.5mn rouble fine for not deleting “prohibited content.” Given the fine is not at all an immense one, it’s being seen as largely a symbolic act portending more punitive action to come.

Tyler Durden
Wed, 09/29/2021 – 14:00

via ZeroHedge News https://ift.tt/3AT7ifn Tyler Durden

The First Amendment and Restrictions on “Off-Site” Signs

The Court is considering, in City of Austin v. Reagan National Advertising, whether certain kinds of limits on “off-site” signs are unconstitutionally content-based; the Fifth Circuit said they are unconstitutional, but other courts are split. I thought I’d pass along an amicus brief we just filed on behalf of the Cato Institute, cosigned by Ilya Shapiro and Trevor Burrus (Cato) and drafted by my students Elizabeth Anastasi, Daniel McDonald Meeter, and Aris Prince, and me, with a very useful suggestion by Simon Ruhland. (Thanks also, as always, to Scott & Cyan Banister, whose support makes the Clinic possible.)

Summary of Argument

The City of Austin’s sign code is content-based:

  1. Austin’s sign code restricts the placement of digital signs based on their content by restricting “off-premises” signs “advertising a business, per­son, activity, goods, products, or services not located on the site where the sign is installed, or that direct[] persons to any location not on that site.” J.A. 52. Enforcing the sign code thus “require[s] enforcement authorities to examine the content of the message that is conveyed to determine whether a violation has occurred.” McCullen Coakley, 573 U.S. 464, 479 (2014)(citations omitted).
  2. This “examine the content of the message conveyed” test is consistent with the majority and the concurrence in Reed Town of Gilbert—which conclude that a restriction is content-based if it “depend[s] . . . on the communicative content of the sign[s],” 576 U.S. 155, 164 (2015)—and with this Court’s earlier cases.
  3. Austin’s sign code improperly prefers commercial speech over political, religious, or otherwise ideological noncommercial speech. This is because, of the premises suitable to billboards, the great bulk are likely to conduct commercial activities rather than ideological ones.
  4. For similar reasons, Austin’s sign code improperly prefers popular noncommercial speech over unpopular noncommercial speech: Many more premises conduct popular ideological activities—and can thus put up digital signs related to those activities—than unpopular activities.
  5. Austin’s sign code prevents speakers who want to use digital signs from remaining anonymous, thus chilling unpopular, minority, and anonymous speech.

Argument

[I.] Austin’s Sign Code Is Facially Content-Based Under McCullen and Reed Because It Requires Officials to Examine the Communicative Content of Signs

The Austin sign code “requires enforcement authorities to examine the content of the message that is conveyed to determine whether a violation has occurred” and is thus facially content-based. McCullen, 573 U.S. at 479 (citing FCC v. League of Women Voters of Cal., 468 U.S. 364, 383 (1984)).

For example, a digital sign displayed outside a Catholic church stating that “Church services start at 9 am on Sunday” would be an on-premises sign that is permitted under the sign code. But if that same sign asked viewers to “Vote for Pro-Life Ballot Measure 123,” the sign would likely be an invalid off-premises sign because it promotes an activity—voting—which is not carried out on church premises. It is thus “apparent . . . that the ordinance distinguishes . . . between permissible and impermissible signs at a particular location by reference to their content.” Metromedia, Inc. v. City of San Diego, 453 U.S. 490, 516 (1981) (plurality opinion) (cleaned up). And if the City decided to allow the sign on the grounds that the Catholic Church is involved in the broader “activity” of supporting pro-life positions, that would make the content discrimination even more obvious, since the City would then have to examine organizations’ overall ideological stands to decide what digital signs they can put up.

Like the distinction between ideological and political signs in Reed, Austin’s sign code requires the government to “identif[y] various categories of signs based on the type of information they convey, then subject[] each category to different restrictions.” 576 U.S. at 159. For instance, Austin’s sign code would prohibit a dry cleaner from displaying a digital sign expressing Hindu beliefs because it is displaying the wrong type of content: content unrelated to dry-cleaning activities. It does not matter that this sign could technically be displayed in a different location, such as a Hindu temple. It is still the subject matter of the sign—Hindu beliefs and not opinions about cleaning—that makes the cleaner’s sign impermissible.

And because it is facially content-based, Austin’s sign code intrinsically treats broad ideological messages differently from other messages. Consider, for instance, a digital sign reading “Question Authority,” “Say No to the War in the Persian Gulf, Call Congress Now” (see City of Ladue v. Gilleo, 512 U.S. 43, 45 (1994)), “China Out of Tibet,” or “Never Trust Anyone Over Thirty.” If the signs are viewed as “advertising a[n] . . . activity . . . not located on the site,” J.A. 52 (for instance, the activity of viewers eventually questioning, calling Congress, advocating Chinese withdrawal, or not trusting), then the digital signs would be allowed nearly nowhere. Perhaps they could appear at a pacifist commune or a Peter Pan fan club (or perhaps not even there), but it is unlikely that these places exist in any great numbers in Austin—people supposedly try to “Keep Austin Weird,” but not that weird.

On the other hand, if some of these signs are viewed as not advertising any activity at all (or if the activities of questioning, believing, or not trusting are seen as happening everywhere, including on the site), they would therefore not be viewed as off-premises, and would be allowed everywhere. Cf. Pet. 17a (“How could one determine whether a digital billboard that said ‘God Loves You’ is on-premises or off-premises?”). Either way, the code would discriminate based on the content of those messages.

Nor can Austin’s sign code be deemed content-neutral on the grounds that it does not expressly single out any particular viewpoint. “The First Amendment’s hostility to content-based regulation [also] extends . . . to prohibition of public discussion of an entire topic.” See Reed, 576 U.S. at 165 (holding that a sign code was content-based because it distinguished ideological, political, and temporary direction signs, even though the categories were not focused on viewpoint). And the code cannot be deemed content-neutral just because the restriction depends on a combination of location and content: When a restriction “describes impermissible [speech] not [only] in terms of time, place, and manner, but [also] in terms of subject matter,” it is content-based. Police Dep’t of City of Chicago v. Mosley, 408 U.S. 92, 99 (1972).

[II.] An “Examine the Content of the Sign” Test Is Consistent with This Court’s Jurisprudence and the Reed Concurrence

This “examine the content of the sign” test is thus called for by Reed and McCullen, and it is also called for by this Court’s pre-Reed cases. For example, in FCC v. League of Women Voters, this Court found a regulation to be content-based because it was “defined solely on the basis of the content of the suppressed speech,” requiring “enforcement authorities [to] necessarily examine the content of the message that is conveyed to determine whether the views expressed concern ‘controversial issues of public importance.'” 468 U.S. at 383.

Similarly, in Arkansas Writers’ Project, Inc. v. Ragland, the Court held that a tax exemption for ma­ga­zines “uniformly devoted to religion or sports” was content-based because “[i]n order to determine whe­ther a magazine is subject to sales tax, Arkansas’ ‘enforcement authorities must necessarily examine the content of the message that is conveyed.'” 481 U.S. 221, 230 (1987) (quoting League of Women Voters, 468 U.S. at 383). Here too, Austin officials must examine signs to see if they direct viewers to off-premises activity.

In Forsyth County v. Nationalist Movement, the Court likewise ruled that a security fee requirement for parades was content-based because “in order to assess accurately the cost of security for parade participants, the administrator ‘must necessarily examine the content of the message that is conveyed,’ estimate the response of others to that content, and judge the number of police necessary to meet that response.” 505 U.S. 123, 134 (1992) (quoting Arkansas Writers’ Project, 481 U.S. at 230). And in Regan v. Time, Inc., the Court ruled that, when a law banning reproductions of currency exempted newsworthy or educational uses, it was content-based:

A determination concerning the newsworthiness or educational value of a photograph cannot help but be based on the content of the photograph and the message it delivers. Under the statute, one photographic reproduction will be allowed and another disallowed solely because the Government determines that the message being conveyed in the one is newsworthy or educational while the message imparted by the other is not.

468 U.S. 641, 648 (1984).

Austin’s sign code similarly “cannot help but be based on the content of the [sign] and the message it delivers.” See id. Under the Austin sign code, one sign will be allowed and another disallowed “solely because the Government determines that the message being conveyed in the one is [advertising activities on the premises in which it is displayed] while the message imparted by the other is not.” Id.

Of course, Austin “has ample content neutral options available to resolve the problems of safety and aesthetics.” Reed, 576 U.S. at 173. Many sign regulations “would not be content based,” including certain “[r]ules distinguishing between on-premises and off premises-signs.” Id. at 174-75 (Alito, J., concurring). For example, an on/off-premises distinction that “favor[ed] [signs] used solely in the business of their owners [or expressed their owners’ preferred nonbusiness views], as distinguished from [signs] which are operated for hire by [third parties]” would distinguish between on- and off-premises signs based on whether signs are rented out to off-premises speakers, not based on their content. Railway Express Agency, Inc. v. New York, 336 U.S. 106, 116 (1949) (Jackson, J., concurring). But, as discussed above, Austin’s sign code does focus on content.

[III.] Austin’s Sign Code Favors Commercial Speech Over Noncommercial Speech

Under Austin’s sign code, commercial premises may put up digital signs related to their business but generally may not put up noncommercial messages. For example, Austin’s sign code would let a restaurant owner post a digital sign saying, “Buy our coffee,” but not one saying “Attend the Anti-War Rally Tomorrow Downtown,” given that the anti-war message is unrelated to the activity on the premises. See Solantic, LLC v. City of Neptune Beach, 410 F.3d 1250, 1264 (11th Cir. 2005) (striking down a sign code that would allow a neon sign reading “Parking in Back” on a homeowner’s premises to be posted indefinitely, but not allow a political message such as “Bring Our Troops Home”).

The sign code thus sharply limits the digital signs available for noncommercial speech, since far more premises are dedicated to selling commercial goods than are dedicated to noncommercial ideological activities. Because “noncommercial signage, such as a political advertisement or religious proclamation, rarely has a locational component, it is almost always off-premises in a literal sense.” Brian J. Connolly & Alan C. Wein­stein, Sign Regulation After Reed: Suggestions for Coping with Legal Uncertainty, 47 Urb. Law. 569, 592 (2015). Yet cities “may not conclude that the communication of commercial information concerning goods and services connected with a particular site is of greater value than the communication of noncommercial messages.” Metromedia, 453 U.S. at 516 (plurality opinion).

And the sign code sharply limits noncommercial counterspeech to commercial speech. Apple, for instance, can advertise its brand and products from signs on any one of its many stores. But organizations or individuals who want to criticize Apple’s data privacy practices could not rent space on a digital sign across the street unless they actually rented the whole building and used it as a place of operations. Likewise, any gun store could have a digital sign advertising guns, but anti-gun organizations could not rent a digital sign to display a “Vote for Gun Control” message.

To be sure, a facially content-neutral law does not become content-based merely because it has a disparate impact, McCullen, 573 U.S. at 480—but for the reasons stated above, Austin’s sign code is not facially content-neutral. The sign code’s practical preference for commercial speech over noncommercial speech is thus relevant to this Court’s analysis.

[IV.] Austin’s Sign Code Favors Popular, Majoritarian Noncommercial Speech Over Unpopular, Minority Noncommercial Speech

Austin’s sign code also prefers noncommercial speech related to popular activities—for instance, popular religious worship services—over noncommercial speech related to unpopular activities. Popular speech, by definition, is an “activity” engaged in at more premises in Austin than is unpopular speech.

Thus, for example, there are about 800 Christian churches and nonprofits in the City of Austin. In contrast, there are only about 30 Jewish nonprofit organizations, 20 Buddhist organizations, and 12 Islamic organizations. So Christian groups will necessarily occupy more premises than will Jewish, Buddhist, and Islamic groups, and will therefore have more space on which they are allowed to express their religious messages on digital signs.

Indeed, religious (or antireligious) groups with no premises at all in Austin would be entirely precluded from posting digital signs discussing their beliefs. And Austin’s sign code similarly privileges popular political groups, which are more likely to have existing premises in Austin, over emerging, small, or out-of-town political groups.

[V.] Austin’s Sign Ordinance Prevents Speakers from Remaining Anonymous, and Thus Unconstitutionally Chills Speech

Many controversial groups might not want to publicly identify their places of business in a way visible to any passerby—they might worry that such identification may draw vandalism of their offices, or at least harassment of their employees or visitors. Yet any such group in Austin would be entirely unable to put up digital signs and still remain anonymous: Under Austin’s sign code, any legal digitized ideological sign implicitly signals that activities related to this ideology are taking place at that very location. Such a “ban on anonymous speech violate[s] the First Amendment,” Buckley v. Am. Const. L. Found., Inc., 525 U.S. 182, 199 (1999) (citing McIntyre v. Ohio Elections Comm’n, 514 U.S. 334, 347, 357 (1995)), because “the First Amendment, as originally understood, protects anonymous [speech].” Mc­Intyre, 514 U.S. at 359 (Thomas, J., concurring).

In this respect, Austin’s code is like the requirement that petition circulators wear identification badges, which was struck down in Buckley v. Am. Const. L. Found., Inc., 525 U.S. at 200. The “badge requirement,” this Court held, “expose[s] the circulator to the risk of ‘heat of the moment’ harassment” and thus “discourages participation in the petition circulation process by forcing name identification without sufficient cause.” Id. at 199, 200. Likewise, the on-premises requirement for digital signs risks heated, angry reactions from passersby, and thus discourages unpopular organizations from engaging in such speech “by forcing . . . identification” of what is happening at the premises. Id. at 200.

Take a digital sign displaying the message “Be Good Without God—Join the Atheist Movement.” Under the sign code, such a sign can only be displayed on premises that conduct atheist activities. In a town (perhaps not Austin, but one can imagine others) where atheism is highly frowned on, the presence of the sign can open the organization and its employees to “retaliation . . . at the hand of an intolerant society.” McIntyre, 514 U.S. at 357. Yet the group would be unable to diminish the risk of such retaliation by renting a digital sign elsewhere in town, because the sign code would forbid such “off-premises” speech.

Conclusion

Austin’s sign code violates the First Amendment. It is unconstitutional under McCullen, Reed, and other precedents from this Court because it distinguishes between signs based on their content. It impermissibly prefers commercial speech over noncommercial speech, and popular speech over unpopular speech. And it forces organizations that want to use digital signs to visually identify the premises at which their employees and activists work, thus tending to chill unpopular speech. Amicus therefore asks that this Court affirm the judgment of the Fifth Circuit.

from Latest – Reason.com https://ift.tt/3Fdrg7d
via IFTTT

Fact-Checkers Replaced By Unicorns After Biden Tweets “My Build Back Better Agenda Costs Zero Dollars”

Fact-Checkers Replaced By Unicorns After Biden Tweets “My Build Back Better Agenda Costs Zero Dollars”

Authored by Mike Shedlock via MishTalk.com,

Biden’s $3.5 trillion Build Back Better plan actually costs nothing says Biden…

Charge of the Unicorns

The opening sentence of Biden’s Tweet, is of course idiotic.

For those who think it is a typo, and Biden meant something else, Biden made the same statement at a press conference last week.

Every time I hear this is going to cost A, B, C, or D—the truth is, based on the commitment that I made, it’s going to cost nothing,” said Biden.

Fact Checkers Missing in Action

Where are the Democratic fact checkers when you need them?

Even if you grant Biden allowances that he really meant “My package will be fully paid for by tax hikes,” it’s still a lie.

Pelosi Covers Up for Biden

Let’s not talk about numbers, let’s talk about values,” said Speaker Pelosi in the above clip.

Lies,  Gimmicks, and Phony Numbers

To make the package seemingly appear as if taxes will cover it Budget Tricks Disguise the True Cost of Biden’s Vast Entitlement Plans.

  1. Start with the child allowance, which is among the bill’s most expensive provisions. Extending the $3,000 to $3,600 per-child payments for a decade would cost roughly $1.1 trillion. That’s as much as all of the income tax increases on individuals passed by the House Ways and Means Committee. Democrats have hidden the real cost by extending the allowance only through 2025. Even if Republicans gain control of Congress and the White House in 2024, Democrats and their media allies will bludgeon them to extend the payments, which will cost another $110 billion each year. [For 5 years – Total $550 billion]

  2. Democrats are using a different time shift to disguise the cost of their Medicare expansion. New vision and hearing benefits would kick in over the next two years and cost about $20 billion a year. But Democrats are delaying the phase-in of the much more expensive dental benefit to 2028. This “saves” $420 billion over 10 years, but the costs explode after that. [Cost $420 Billion minimum in future years]

  3. Then there’s the new universal child-care entitlement, which gives $90 billion to the states—but only from 2022 to 2027. But what happens when the $90 billion runs out, which may occur before the 2027 expiration? The bill automatically appropriates “such sums as may be necessary for each of fiscal years 2025 through 2027.” [Cost $90 billion plus any shortfalls to 2027]

  4.  Democrats also charge states with standing up a universal pre-K entitlement, which would start next year and run through 2028. The House Education and Labor Committee bill doesn’t specify an appropriation, but President Biden’s budget projects this new entitlement would cost $33 billion a year when fully phased in. [This one kicks back to a state responsibility, but who really believes that? I don’t, so factor in another 33 billion for 4 years totaling $132 billion.]

10-Year Shifty Math

Biden uses an arbitrary stop date of 2025 on child allowances, a start date on dental of 2028, a stop date on child care of 2027, and a stop date of 2028 on “free” college.

In practice, once entitlements are granted, they are never taken away. 

Total up the shortfalls over a 10 year period and Biden will need to come up with another $1.192 trillion in taxes on top of his proposed tax hikes.

Another problem in all of this is projected economic gains and tax revenues never meet promises. Never really means never.  

For example, Biden estimates that expanding the IRS would bring in $463 billion, but the CBO projects $120 billion. 

Oops, that another $343 billion shortfall. 

Factor that in and you have a shortfall of $1.5 trillion or so on a $3.5 trillion deal, and that does not count the $1 trillion infrastructure deal. 

Brain Trust With No Brain

For discussion of Biden’s IRS proposal, please see Biden Wants to Fix a $7 Trillion Tax Evasion Problem With a Brain Trust

*  *  *

Like these reports? If so, please Subscribe to MishTalk Email Alerts.

Tyler Durden
Wed, 09/29/2021 – 13:40

via ZeroHedge News https://ift.tt/3EZPwtc Tyler Durden

One Bank Finds That There Is Actually Too Little Corporate Debt

One Bank Finds That There Is Actually Too Little Corporate Debt

By now it is common knowledge (or we hope it is) that there is just way too much debt in the world, with the IIF calculating earlier this month that global debt hit a record $296 billion in Q2, up $36 trillion since covid, representing almost 360% of global GDP.

Yet in an unexpected twist, this morning BofA’s credit strategists made the “surprising” discovery that corporate debt has never been lower… at least when compared to the amount of corporate equity.

As Bank of America strategist Hans Mikkelsen writes, “financial debt (bonds and loans) of US Non-financial corporations fell to a record low 23% of the market value of equity in in 2Q-2021 from 25% the prior quarter (Figure 1).

Amusingly, and in what we assume is an attempt at institutional trolling, Mikkelsen then says that while some have argued over the years there is too much corporate debt (Figure 2), “that suggests instead there is either too much corporate equity or too little corporate debt, or both.”

While it’s unclear if the chief BofA credit strategist was being facetious or joking, luckily he answered his own rhetorical question by noting that “assets have struggled historically following low values for this leverage ratio (4Q-1972, 1Q-2000, 2Q-2007).”

Why? Because what this completely meaningless ratio reveals is that while we may have a corporate debt bubble (and we do), it’s far smaller than the equity bubble, hence why the denominator (market value of equity) is massive enough to make the total debt amount small. And, no surprise, the ratio hits record lows when there are equity bubbles like in 2000 and 2007, which is also why assets “struggle” after… because what happens after the equity bubble peaks is far less pleasant. The only question is how much further will central banks keep inflating the current bubble which also happens to be the biggest of all time.

Tyler Durden
Wed, 09/29/2021 – 13:21

via ZeroHedge News https://ift.tt/3upwmrZ Tyler Durden

The First Amendment and Restrictions on “Off-Site” Signs

The Court is considering, in City of Austin v. Reagan National Advertising, whether certain kinds of limits on “off-site” signs are unconstitutionally content-based; the Fifth Circuit said they are unconstitutional, but other courts are split. I thought I’d pass along an amicus brief we just filed on behalf of the Cato Institute, cosigned by Ilya Shapiro and Trevor Burrus (Cato) and drafted by my students Elizabeth Anastasi, Daniel McDonald Meeter, and Aris Prince, and me, with a very useful suggestion by Simon Ruhland. (Thanks also, as always, to Scott & Cyan Banister, whose support makes the Clinic possible.)

Summary of Argument

The City of Austin’s sign code is content-based:

  1. Austin’s sign code restricts the placement of digital signs based on their content by restricting “off-premises” signs “advertising a business, per­son, activity, goods, products, or services not located on the site where the sign is installed, or that direct[] persons to any location not on that site.” J.A. 52. Enforcing the sign code thus “require[s] enforcement authorities to examine the content of the message that is conveyed to determine whether a violation has occurred.” McCullen Coakley, 573 U.S. 464, 479 (2014)(citations omitted).
  2. This “examine the content of the message conveyed” test is consistent with the majority and the concurrence in Reed Town of Gilbert—which conclude that a restriction is content-based if it “depend[s] . . . on the communicative content of the sign[s],” 576 U.S. 155, 164 (2015)—and with this Court’s earlier cases.
  3. Austin’s sign code improperly prefers commercial speech over political, religious, or otherwise ideological noncommercial speech. This is because, of the premises suitable to billboards, the great bulk are likely to conduct commercial activities rather than ideological ones.
  4. For similar reasons, Austin’s sign code improperly prefers popular noncommercial speech over unpopular noncommercial speech: Many more premises conduct popular ideological activities—and can thus put up digital signs related to those activities—than unpopular activities.
  5. Austin’s sign code prevents speakers who want to use digital signs from remaining anonymous, thus chilling unpopular, minority, and anonymous speech.

Argument

[I.] Austin’s Sign Code Is Facially Content-Based Under McCullen and Reed Because It Requires Officials to Examine the Communicative Content of Signs

The Austin sign code “requires enforcement authorities to examine the content of the message that is conveyed to determine whether a violation has occurred” and is thus facially content-based. McCullen, 573 U.S. at 479 (citing FCC v. League of Women Voters of Cal., 468 U.S. 364, 383 (1984)).

For example, a digital sign displayed outside a Catholic church stating that “Church services start at 9 am on Sunday” would be an on-premises sign that is permitted under the sign code. But if that same sign asked viewers to “Vote for Pro-Life Ballot Measure 123,” the sign would likely be an invalid off-premises sign because it promotes an activity—voting—which is not carried out on church premises. It is thus “apparent . . . that the ordinance distinguishes . . . between permissible and impermissible signs at a particular location by reference to their content.” Metromedia, Inc. v. City of San Diego, 453 U.S. 490, 516 (1981) (plurality opinion) (cleaned up). And if the City decided to allow the sign on the grounds that the Catholic Church is involved in the broader “activity” of supporting pro-life positions, that would make the content discrimination even more obvious, since the City would then have to examine organizations’ overall ideological stands to decide what digital signs they can put up.

Like the distinction between ideological and political signs in Reed, Austin’s sign code requires the government to “identif[y] various categories of signs based on the type of information they convey, then subject[] each category to different restrictions.” 576 U.S. at 159. For instance, Austin’s sign code would prohibit a dry cleaner from displaying a digital sign expressing Hindu beliefs because it is displaying the wrong type of content: content unrelated to dry-cleaning activities. It does not matter that this sign could technically be displayed in a different location, such as a Hindu temple. It is still the subject matter of the sign—Hindu beliefs and not opinions about cleaning—that makes the cleaner’s sign impermissible.

And because it is facially content-based, Austin’s sign code intrinsically treats broad ideological messages differently from other messages. Consider, for instance, a digital sign reading “Question Authority,” “Say No to the War in the Persian Gulf, Call Congress Now” (see City of Ladue v. Gilleo, 512 U.S. 43, 45 (1994)), “China Out of Tibet,” or “Never Trust Anyone Over Thirty.” If the signs are viewed as “advertising a[n] . . . activity . . . not located on the site,” J.A. 52 (for instance, the activity of viewers eventually questioning, calling Congress, advocating Chinese withdrawal, or not trusting), then the digital signs would be allowed nearly nowhere. Perhaps they could appear at a pacifist commune or a Peter Pan fan club (or perhaps not even there), but it is unlikely that these places exist in any great numbers in Austin—people supposedly try to “Keep Austin Weird,” but not that weird.

On the other hand, if some of these signs are viewed as not advertising any activity at all (or if the activities of questioning, believing, or not trusting are seen as happening everywhere, including on the site), they would therefore not be viewed as off-premises, and would be allowed everywhere. Cf. Pet. 17a (“How could one determine whether a digital billboard that said ‘God Loves You’ is on-premises or off-premises?”). Either way, the code would discriminate based on the content of those messages.

Nor can Austin’s sign code be deemed content-neutral on the grounds that it does not expressly single out any particular viewpoint. “The First Amendment’s hostility to content-based regulation [also] extends . . . to prohibition of public discussion of an entire topic.” See Reed, 576 U.S. at 165 (holding that a sign code was content-based because it distinguished ideological, political, and temporary direction signs, even though the categories were not focused on viewpoint). And the code cannot be deemed content-neutral just because the restriction depends on a combination of location and content: When a restriction “describes impermissible [speech] not [only] in terms of time, place, and manner, but [also] in terms of subject matter,” it is content-based. Police Dep’t of City of Chicago v. Mosley, 408 U.S. 92, 99 (1972).

[II.] An “Examine the Content of the Sign” Test Is Consistent with This Court’s Jurisprudence and the Reed Concurrence

This “examine the content of the sign” test is thus called for by Reed and McCullen, and it is also called for by this Court’s pre-Reed cases. For example, in FCC v. League of Women Voters, this Court found a regulation to be content-based because it was “defined solely on the basis of the content of the suppressed speech,” requiring “enforcement authorities [to] necessarily examine the content of the message that is conveyed to determine whether the views expressed concern ‘controversial issues of public importance.'” 468 U.S. at 383.

Similarly, in Arkansas Writers’ Project, Inc. v. Ragland, the Court held that a tax exemption for ma­ga­zines “uniformly devoted to religion or sports” was content-based because “[i]n order to determine whe­ther a magazine is subject to sales tax, Arkansas’ ‘enforcement authorities must necessarily examine the content of the message that is conveyed.'” 481 U.S. 221, 230 (1987) (quoting League of Women Voters, 468 U.S. at 383). Here too, Austin officials must examine signs to see if they direct viewers to off-premises activity.

In Forsyth County v. Nationalist Movement, the Court likewise ruled that a security fee requirement for parades was content-based because “in order to assess accurately the cost of security for parade participants, the administrator ‘must necessarily examine the content of the message that is conveyed,’ estimate the response of others to that content, and judge the number of police necessary to meet that response.” 505 U.S. 123, 134 (1992) (quoting Arkansas Writers’ Project, 481 U.S. at 230). And in Regan v. Time, Inc., the Court ruled that, when a law banning reproductions of currency exempted newsworthy or educational uses, it was content-based:

A determination concerning the newsworthiness or educational value of a photograph cannot help but be based on the content of the photograph and the message it delivers. Under the statute, one photographic reproduction will be allowed and another disallowed solely because the Government determines that the message being conveyed in the one is newsworthy or educational while the message imparted by the other is not.

468 U.S. 641, 648 (1984).

Austin’s sign code similarly “cannot help but be based on the content of the [sign] and the message it delivers.” See id. Under the Austin sign code, one sign will be allowed and another disallowed “solely because the Government determines that the message being conveyed in the one is [advertising activities on the premises in which it is displayed] while the message imparted by the other is not.” Id.

Of course, Austin “has ample content neutral options available to resolve the problems of safety and aesthetics.” Reed, 576 U.S. at 173. Many sign regulations “would not be content based,” including certain “[r]ules distinguishing between on-premises and off premises-signs.” Id. at 174-75 (Alito, J., concurring). For example, an on/off-premises distinction that “favor[ed] [signs] used solely in the business of their owners [or expressed their owners’ preferred nonbusiness views], as distinguished from [signs] which are operated for hire by [third parties]” would distinguish between on- and off-premises signs based on whether signs are rented out to off-premises speakers, not based on their content. Railway Express Agency, Inc. v. New York, 336 U.S. 106, 116 (1949) (Jackson, J., concurring). But, as discussed above, Austin’s sign code does focus on content.

[III.] Austin’s Sign Code Favors Commercial Speech Over Noncommercial Speech

Under Austin’s sign code, commercial premises may put up digital signs related to their business but generally may not put up noncommercial messages. For example, Austin’s sign code would let a restaurant owner post a digital sign saying, “Buy our coffee,” but not one saying “Attend the Anti-War Rally Tomorrow Downtown,” given that the anti-war message is unrelated to the activity on the premises. See Solantic, LLC v. City of Neptune Beach, 410 F.3d 1250, 1264 (11th Cir. 2005) (striking down a sign code that would allow a neon sign reading “Parking in Back” on a homeowner’s premises to be posted indefinitely, but not allow a political message such as “Bring Our Troops Home”).

The sign code thus sharply limits the digital signs available for noncommercial speech, since far more premises are dedicated to selling commercial goods than are dedicated to noncommercial ideological activities. Because “noncommercial signage, such as a political advertisement or religious proclamation, rarely has a locational component, it is almost always off-premises in a literal sense.” Brian J. Connolly & Alan C. Wein­stein, Sign Regulation After Reed: Suggestions for Coping with Legal Uncertainty, 47 Urb. Law. 569, 592 (2015). Yet cities “may not conclude that the communication of commercial information concerning goods and services connected with a particular site is of greater value than the communication of noncommercial messages.” Metromedia, 453 U.S. at 516 (plurality opinion).

And the sign code sharply limits noncommercial counterspeech to commercial speech. Apple, for instance, can advertise its brand and products from signs on any one of its many stores. But organizations or individuals who want to criticize Apple’s data privacy practices could not rent space on a digital sign across the street unless they actually rented the whole building and used it as a place of operations. Likewise, any gun store could have a digital sign advertising guns, but anti-gun organizations could not rent a digital sign to display a “Vote for Gun Control” message.

To be sure, a facially content-neutral law does not become content-based merely because it has a disparate impact, McCullen, 573 U.S. at 480—but for the reasons stated above, Austin’s sign code is not facially content-neutral. The sign code’s practical preference for commercial speech over noncommercial speech is thus relevant to this Court’s analysis.

[IV.] Austin’s Sign Code Favors Popular, Majoritarian Noncommercial Speech Over Unpopular, Minority Noncommercial Speech

Austin’s sign code also prefers noncommercial speech related to popular activities—for instance, popular religious worship services—over noncommercial speech related to unpopular activities. Popular speech, by definition, is an “activity” engaged in at more premises in Austin than is unpopular speech.

Thus, for example, there are about 800 Christian churches and nonprofits in the City of Austin. In contrast, there are only about 30 Jewish nonprofit organizations, 20 Buddhist organizations, and 12 Islamic organizations. So Christian groups will necessarily occupy more premises than will Jewish, Buddhist, and Islamic groups, and will therefore have more space on which they are allowed to express their religious messages on digital signs.

Indeed, religious (or antireligious) groups with no premises at all in Austin would be entirely precluded from posting digital signs discussing their beliefs. And Austin’s sign code similarly privileges popular political groups, which are more likely to have existing premises in Austin, over emerging, small, or out-of-town political groups.

[V.] Austin’s Sign Ordinance Prevents Speakers from Remaining Anonymous, and Thus Unconstitutionally Chills Speech

Many controversial groups might not want to publicly identify their places of business in a way visible to any passerby—they might worry that such identification may draw vandalism of their offices, or at least harassment of their employees or visitors. Yet any such group in Austin would be entirely unable to put up digital signs and still remain anonymous: Under Austin’s sign code, any legal digitized ideological sign implicitly signals that activities related to this ideology are taking place at that very location. Such a “ban on anonymous speech violate[s] the First Amendment,” Buckley v. Am. Const. L. Found., Inc., 525 U.S. 182, 199 (1999) (citing McIntyre v. Ohio Elections Comm’n, 514 U.S. 334, 347, 357 (1995)), because “the First Amendment, as originally understood, protects anonymous [speech].” Mc­Intyre, 514 U.S. at 359 (Thomas, J., concurring).

In this respect, Austin’s code is like the requirement that petition circulators wear identification badges, which was struck down in Buckley v. Am. Const. L. Found., Inc., 525 U.S. at 200. The “badge requirement,” this Court held, “expose[s] the circulator to the risk of ‘heat of the moment’ harassment” and thus “discourages participation in the petition circulation process by forcing name identification without sufficient cause.” Id. at 199, 200. Likewise, the on-premises requirement for digital signs risks heated, angry reactions from passersby, and thus discourages unpopular organizations from engaging in such speech “by forcing . . . identification” of what is happening at the premises. Id. at 200.

Take a digital sign displaying the message “Be Good Without God—Join the Atheist Movement.” Under the sign code, such a sign can only be displayed on premises that conduct atheist activities. In a town (perhaps not Austin, but one can imagine others) where atheism is highly frowned on, the presence of the sign can open the organization and its employees to “retaliation . . . at the hand of an intolerant society.” McIntyre, 514 U.S. at 357. Yet the group would be unable to diminish the risk of such retaliation by renting a digital sign elsewhere in town, because the sign code would forbid such “off-premises” speech.

Conclusion

Austin’s sign code violates the First Amendment. It is unconstitutional under McCullen, Reed, and other precedents from this Court because it distinguishes between signs based on their content. It impermissibly prefers commercial speech over noncommercial speech, and popular speech over unpopular speech. And it forces organizations that want to use digital signs to visually identify the premises at which their employees and activists work, thus tending to chill unpopular speech. Amicus therefore asks that this Court affirm the judgment of the Fifth Circuit.

from Latest – Reason.com https://ift.tt/3Fdrg7d
via IFTTT

Seattle City Council Passes Rent Control by Another Name. Is It Legal?


reason-seattle2

The Seattle City Council might have found a clever way around Washington state’s ban on local rent control policies. On Monday, it passed two bills that respectively require landlords to give generous notice to their tenants of any rent increases and to provide relocation expenses to low-income renters who do move in response to large rent hikes.

Current city and state law require landlords to give their tenants 60 days’ notice of any rent increase. One bill passed by the council would increase that notification period to 180 days, likely the longest notification period in the country.

And if a low-income tenant decides to move in response to a rent increase of 10 percent or more, landlords will be obligated to provide them with “economic dislocation relocation assistance” equal to three months’ rent, thanks to another bill passed by the council on Monday.

Both are the handiwork of Councilmember Kshama Sawant, a member of the Socialist Alternative party, who argues the twin bills are needed to protect tenants from a post-pandemic upswing in rents—and from capitalism more generally.

“Today’s victories will benefit tens of thousands of renters in Seattle, who are facing skyrocketing rent increases from profit-hungry corporate landlords and the venture capitalists and big banks who are [fueling] a speculative bubble,” said Sawant after the bills passed.

Landlords were less pleased with the bills’ passage, arguing during public comment that they’d raise their costs of doing business and are, per the Seattle Times, tantamount to rent control.

That latter charge could open up the new bills to legal challenges.

Washington state law preempts municipal governments from enacting laws “which regulate the amount of rent to be charged” and instead reserves that power under the state government.

That law should preempt Seattle’s 180-day notice requirement, says William Shadbolt, a lawyer with the Rental Housing Association of Washington’s (RHAWA) Legal Defense Fund.

While the notification bill doesn’t put a cap on rent increases, as rent control laws in Oregon and California do, it is limiting when a particular rent increase goes into effect. That is clearly a regulation on the “amount” being charged, he says.

The prior requirement that landlords give tenants 60 days’ notice of rent increases was a standard set in state law, while the new 180-day notice requirement is unique to Seattle.

The relocation assistance bill could be vulnerable to a legal challenge as well.

Landlords in Portland, Oregon, sued their city government over a similar policy requiring landlords to pay relocation expenses to tenants who move in response to a 10 percent rent increase. They argued that this was clearly intended to deter landlords from raising rents beyond a certain level and thus banned by Oregon’s preemption of local rent control laws.

That challenge was rejected at the county and appellate court levels. The Oregon Supreme Court held a hearing on the case earlier this year.

A recent Supreme Court decision striking down part of New York state’s eviction moratorium could also pose a danger to Seattle’s relocation assistance bill.

That decision, in the case Chrysafis v. Marks, invalidated a section of the moratorium allowing tenants to self-certify that they had suffered economic hardship, and thus were protected from eviction under the state law. That violated landlords’ due process rights because it didn’t give them an opportunity to contest tenants’ self-declaration that they were protected by the moratorium, ruled the court.

Seattle’s rent relocation assistance bill—which only covers tenants making up to 80 percent of area median income—likewise allows tenants to self-certify their income, and thus could be vulnerable to a similar legal challenge, says Shadbolt.

He says the RHAWA is currently reviewing the legislation to see if they’ll file a lawsuit.

Sawant herself has described her bills as adding momentum for “a full renters’ Bill of Rights, which includes citywide rent control with no corporate loopholes.”

Both bills will now go to Mayor Jenny Durkan for her signature.

from Latest – Reason.com https://ift.tt/3odEIlk
via IFTTT